25.06.2013 Views

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

440 14. Gestion <strong>de</strong> Portefeuilles multimoments <strong>et</strong> équilibre <strong>de</strong> marché<br />

In the standard Gaussian framework, the multivari<strong>at</strong>e distribution takes the form of an exponential of minus<br />

a quadr<strong>at</strong>ic form X ′ Ω −1 X, where X is the unicolumn of ass<strong>et</strong> r<strong>et</strong>urns and Ω is their covariance m<strong>at</strong>rix. The<br />

beauty and simplicity of the Gaussian case is th<strong>at</strong> the essentially impossible task of d<strong>et</strong>ermining a large multidimensional<br />

function is reduced into the very much simpler one of calcul<strong>at</strong>ing the N(N + 1)/2 elements<br />

of the symm<strong>et</strong>ric covariance m<strong>at</strong>rix. Risk is then uniquely and compl<strong>et</strong>ely embodied by the variance of the<br />

portfolio r<strong>et</strong>urn, which is easily d<strong>et</strong>ermined from the covariance m<strong>at</strong>rix. This is the basis of Markovitz’s<br />

portfolio theory (Markovitz 1959) and of the CAPM (see for instance (Merton 1990)).<br />

However, as is well-known, the variance (vol<strong>at</strong>ility) of portfolio r<strong>et</strong>urns provi<strong>de</strong>s <strong>at</strong> best a limited quantific<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

of incurred risks, as the empirical distributions of r<strong>et</strong>urns have “f<strong>at</strong> tails” (Lux 1996, Gopikrishnan <strong>et</strong><br />

al. 1998) and the <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nces b<strong>et</strong>ween ass<strong>et</strong>s are only imperfectly accounted for by the covariance m<strong>at</strong>rix<br />

(Litterman and Winkelmann 1998).<br />

In this section, we present a novel approach based on (Sorn<strong>et</strong>te <strong>et</strong> al. 2000b) to <strong>at</strong>tack this problem in terms<br />

of the param<strong>et</strong>eriz<strong>at</strong>ion of the multivari<strong>at</strong>e distribution of r<strong>et</strong>urns involving two steps: (i) the projection of<br />

the empirical marginal distributions onto Gaussian laws via nonlinear mappings; (ii) the use of an entropy<br />

maximiz<strong>at</strong>ion to construct the corresponding most parsimonious represent<strong>at</strong>ion of the multivari<strong>at</strong>e distribution.<br />

6.1 A brief exposition and justific<strong>at</strong>ion of the m<strong>et</strong>hod<br />

We will use the m<strong>et</strong>hod of d<strong>et</strong>ermin<strong>at</strong>ion of multivari<strong>at</strong>e distributions introduced by (Karlen 1998) and<br />

(Sorn<strong>et</strong>te <strong>et</strong> al. 2000b). This m<strong>et</strong>hod consists in two steps: (i) transform each r<strong>et</strong>urn x into a Gaussian<br />

variable y by a nonlinear monotonous increasing mapping; (ii) use the principle of entropy maximiz<strong>at</strong>ion to<br />

construct the corresponding multivari<strong>at</strong>e distribution of the transformed variables y.<br />

The first concern to address before going any further is wh<strong>et</strong>her the nonlinear transform<strong>at</strong>ion, which is in<br />

principle different for each ass<strong>et</strong> r<strong>et</strong>urn, conserves the structure of the <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce. In wh<strong>at</strong> sense is the<br />

<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce b<strong>et</strong>ween the transformed variables y the same as the <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce b<strong>et</strong>ween the ass<strong>et</strong> r<strong>et</strong>urns x? It<br />

turns out th<strong>at</strong> the notion of “copulas” provi<strong>de</strong>s a general and rigorous answer which justifies the procedure<br />

of (Sorn<strong>et</strong>te <strong>et</strong> al. 2000b).<br />

For compl<strong>et</strong>eness and use l<strong>at</strong>er on, we briefly recall the <strong>de</strong>finition of a copula (for further d<strong>et</strong>ails about<br />

the concept of copula see (Nelsen 1998)). A function C : [0, 1] n −→ [0, 1] is a n-copula if it enjoys the<br />

following properties :<br />

• ∀u ∈ [0, 1], C(1, · · · , 1, u, 1 · · · , 1) = u ,<br />

• ∀ui ∈ [0, 1], C(u1, · · · , un) = 0 if <strong>at</strong> least one of the ui equals zero ,<br />

• C is groun<strong>de</strong>d and n-increasing, i.e., the C-volume of every boxes whose vertices lie in [0, 1] n is<br />

positive.<br />

Skar’s Theorem then st<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong>, given an n-dimensional distribution function F with continuous marginal<br />

distributions F1, · · · , Fn, there exists a unique n-copula C : [0, 1] n −→ [0, 1] such th<strong>at</strong> :<br />

F (x1, · · · , xn) = C(F1(x1), · · · , Fn(xn)) . (34)<br />

This elegant result shows th<strong>at</strong> the study of the <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce of random variables can be performed in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>ntly<br />

of the behavior of the marginal distributions. Moreover, the following result shows th<strong>at</strong> copulas<br />

are intrinsic measures of <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce. Consi<strong>de</strong>r n continuous random variables X1, · · · , Xn with copula<br />

16

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!