12.07.2015 Views

Download the file - United Nations Rule of Law

Download the file - United Nations Rule of Law

Download the file - United Nations Rule of Law

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

126Security <strong>of</strong> tenureMarket-basedevictions … areincreasing both interms <strong>of</strong> scale …and as a proportion<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total …eviction tallyMarket-drivendisplacements mayalso result from insitu tenure regularization,settlementupgrading and basicservice provisionMarket evictions …can easily generatenew homelessnessand new illegalsettlementsposition taken on <strong>the</strong>se questions under human rights lawmay be one way that a new approach to tenure can beencouraged, particularly when <strong>the</strong>se evictions are carriedout in ways clearly contrary to human rights law. Reducing oreliminating what are <strong>of</strong>ten referred to as ‘market evictions’,however, presents ano<strong>the</strong>r set <strong>of</strong> challenges.Evictions <strong>of</strong> those working in <strong>the</strong> informal economicsector have been registered in a range <strong>of</strong> countries.Operation Murambatsvina (also referred to as OperationRestore Order) in Zimbabwe resulted not only in <strong>the</strong> demolition<strong>of</strong> housing, but in mass evictions <strong>of</strong> informal traders aswell, which, in turn, drastically increased unemploymentand fur<strong>the</strong>r undermined both <strong>the</strong> formal and informaleconomies in <strong>the</strong> country (see also Box 5.14). Additionallarge-scale evictions <strong>of</strong> informal enterprises have beenreported in Bangladesh, where at least 10,868 homes andbusinesses were demolished in 2004, and in Nigeria, wheresome 250,000 traders, kiosks and residences weredestroyed in 1996. 36Market-based evictionsMoralists used to complain that internationallaw was impotent in curbing injustices <strong>of</strong>nation-states; but it has shown even lesscapacity to rein in markets that, after all, do noteven have an address to which subpoenas canbe sent. As <strong>the</strong> product <strong>of</strong> a host <strong>of</strong> individualchoices or singular corporate acts, markets <strong>of</strong>ferno collective responsibility. Yet responsibility is<strong>the</strong> first obligation <strong>of</strong> both citizens and civicinstitutions. 37Ano<strong>the</strong>r key trend shared by most countries – regardless <strong>of</strong>income – is <strong>the</strong> growing phenomenon <strong>of</strong> market-basedevictions. Although precise figures are not available,observers have noted that such evictions are increasing bothin terms <strong>of</strong> scale (e.g. <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> persons/householdsevicted annually) and as a proportion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total globaleviction tally. To cite a not untypical case, it has beenestimated that some 80 per cent <strong>of</strong> households in Kigali,Rwanda, are potentially subject to expropriation or marketdrivenevictions. 38 Market evictions, most <strong>of</strong> which are notmonitored or recorded by housing organizations, which tendto restrict <strong>the</strong>ir focus to forced evictions, are caused by avariety <strong>of</strong> forces. These include urban gentrification; rentalincreases; land titling programmes; private land developmentand o<strong>the</strong>r developmental pressures; expropriation measures;and <strong>the</strong> sale <strong>of</strong> public land to private investors. Marketdrivendisplacements may also result from in-situ tenureregularization, settlement upgrading and basic service provisionwithout involvement <strong>of</strong> community organizations orappropriate accompanying social and economic measures(such as credit facilities, advisory planning or capacitybuildingat community level), and this may give rise toincreases in housing expenditure that <strong>the</strong> poorest segment<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> settlement population is not able to meet. Whencombined with increases in land values and market pressuresresulting from tenure regularization, <strong>the</strong> poorest householdswill be tempted to sell <strong>the</strong>ir property and settle in a locationwhere accommodation costs are less. This commonlyobserved progressive form <strong>of</strong> displacement results in <strong>the</strong>gradual gentrification <strong>of</strong> inner city and suburban low-incomesettlements.Because market-based evictions are seen as inevitableconsequences <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> development process in <strong>the</strong> eyes <strong>of</strong>many public authorities, and due to <strong>the</strong> fact that negotiationsbetween those proposing <strong>the</strong> eviction and those affected arenot uncommon, this manifestation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> eviction process is<strong>of</strong>ten treated as acceptable and even voluntary in nature.Some may even argue (albeit wrongly, in many cases) thatsuch evictions are not illegal under international law andthus are an acceptable policy option. However, one viewsuggests:Disguising a forced eviction as a ‘negotiateddisplacement’ is usually seen as ‘good governance’practice. It is less risky, in political terms,than a forced eviction; it is less brutal and,accordingly, less visible as it can be achievedfollowing individual case-by-case negotiations.Most observers consider that <strong>the</strong> very principle<strong>of</strong> negotiating is more important than <strong>the</strong> terms<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> negotiations, especially regarding <strong>the</strong>compensation issue, even when <strong>the</strong> compensationis unfair and detrimental to <strong>the</strong> occupant. 39While all forms <strong>of</strong> eviction, forced and market based, arelegally governed by <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> human rights law, compensationin <strong>the</strong> event <strong>of</strong> market-based evictions tends to betreated more as a discretionary choice, ra<strong>the</strong>r than a right <strong>of</strong>those forced to relocate. Because one’s informal tenurestatus may limit evictees from exercising rights to compensationand resettlement if <strong>the</strong>y are subjected to marketevictions, <strong>the</strong>se processes can easily generate new homelessnessand new illegal settlements. Even when compensationis provided, it tends to be limited to <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> a dwellingand not <strong>the</strong> dwelling and <strong>the</strong> land plot as a whole, with <strong>the</strong>result being greater social exclusion. In <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> legalremedies, adequate resettlement options or fair and justcompensation, market-based evictions lead to <strong>the</strong> establishment<strong>of</strong> new informal settlements on <strong>the</strong> periphery <strong>of</strong> cities,and tend to increase population pressure and density inexisting informal inner-city settlements. This usually resultsin deterioration in housing conditions and/or increases inhousing expenditure and commuting costs for displacedhouseholds.Expropriation and compulsory acquisitionInternational human rights standards, intergovernmentalorganizations, a growing number <strong>of</strong> governments and manyNGOs have embraced <strong>the</strong> view that forced eviction – or, forthat matter, virtually every type <strong>of</strong> arbitrary or unlawfuldisplacement – raises serious human rights concerns andshould be excluded from <strong>the</strong> realms <strong>of</strong> acceptable policy. Yet,all states and all legal systems retain rights to expropriate orcompulsorily acquire private property, land or housing (e.g.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!