28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

42 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

Influence Market corruption Influence Markets deal in access to,<br />

and influence within, strong state institutions; <strong>of</strong>ten politicians serve as<br />

middlemen, putting their connections out for rent in exchange for contributions<br />

both legal and otherwise.<br />

Mature market democracies <strong>of</strong>fer extensive political and economic<br />

opportunities. They are undergoing only slight liberalization, as there is<br />

not much left to be done, and generally have strong, legitimate institutions.<br />

They resemble each other in important ways, which may help<br />

explain why they are <strong>of</strong>ten held up as reform ideals. Legitimate constitutional<br />

frameworks, political competition, free news media, strong civil<br />

societies, and open economies do help check abuses. But many <strong>of</strong> these<br />

countries have not so much ‘‘solved’’ the corruption problem as they<br />

developed states and political systems accommodating to wealth interests,<br />

fitting the rules to the society as well as persuading people to<br />

follow the law. Most economic dealings take place entirely within their<br />

private sectors under rules much less demanding than those <strong>of</strong> the public<br />

sector, while the political influence <strong>of</strong> wealth follows well-established<br />

channels.<br />

<strong>Corruption</strong> in well-institutionalized market democracies – or at least,<br />

the high-level bribery that tends to influence corruption index scores –<br />

will be the exception, not the rule, and is unlikely to thwart development<br />

(although it is hardly cost-free: see chapter 4). But these societies still<br />

have corruption problems worth worrying about. Some are global: banks<br />

and investment markets in Influence Market countries are <strong>of</strong>ten the<br />

repositories, or participate in the laundering, <strong>of</strong> corrupt gains from elsewhere,<br />

and their multinational businesses have made illicit deals in many<br />

other societies. Most, however, are domestic, and can at times be quite<br />

serious. Influence Market corruption revolves around access to, and<br />

advantages within, established institutions, rather than deals and connections<br />

circumventing them. Strong institutions reduce the opportunities,<br />

and some <strong>of</strong> the incentives, to pursue extra-systemic strategies, while<br />

increasing the risks; moreover the very power <strong>of</strong> those institutions to<br />

deliver major benefits and costs raises the value <strong>of</strong> influence within<br />

them. The role <strong>of</strong> competitive politics in this variety <strong>of</strong> corruption is<br />

complex. It can allow citizens to oust a corrupt government, but the<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> running for <strong>of</strong>fice create incentives for politicians to put their<br />

connections and expertise up for rent, and for parties to keep competition<br />

under control.<br />

Influence Markets thus work mostly ‘‘within the system,’’ another<br />

factor contributing to the relatively favorable corruption scores these<br />

societies receive. Power-oriented corruption will focus on winning <strong>of</strong>fices<br />

and influencing those who hold them; corruption in pursuit <strong>of</strong> wealth will

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!