28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Elite Cartels 95<br />

DC-led coalition that shared power and a pervasive spoils system.<br />

A coalition party could lose a few parliamentary seats at the polls – though<br />

in fact electoral results remained remarkably consistent through most <strong>of</strong><br />

the First Republic era – but still have a place at the trough (Calise, 1994;<br />

Hine, 1995: 193; Buffachi and Burgess, 1998: 5, 11, 87–88; Colazingari<br />

and Rose-Ackerman, 1998: 457–462; Della Porta and Vannucci, 1999,<br />

2002; Della Porta, 2004). After the late 1940s the Communists (PCI)<br />

were an ineffective opposition at the national level, but their presence,<br />

along with anticipated US reaction should they win power, helped bind<br />

the coalition together and enabled it to put pressure upon business contributors<br />

(Rhodes, 1997: 66–72).<br />

Extortion <strong>of</strong> business by party cashiers was common, though <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

bribes and kickbacks were given as a matter <strong>of</strong> course. Some payments<br />

were for specific benefits; more <strong>of</strong>ten they were informal ‘‘taxes’’ paid in<br />

anticipation <strong>of</strong> the protection the parties could afford, be it against the<br />

actions <strong>of</strong> the state or corrupt demands from competing politicians.<br />

Kickbacks on construction contracts <strong>of</strong> 10 percent were a de facto standard.<br />

Party leaders who brokered favorable decisions for businesses could<br />

expect a substantial cut. In an ordinary year during the late 1980s the DC<br />

took in around 60–65 billion Lire (approximately US$40 million), a<br />

figure that rose to around 80–85 billion Lire in election years. Of that<br />

total 16–17 billion Lire was illicit income, some <strong>of</strong> it from business<br />

speculation but much <strong>of</strong> it from bribes (Colazingari and Rose-<br />

Ackerman, 1998: 457–459). <strong>Corruption</strong> may have been made worse by<br />

‘‘reforms’’ in 1974 that barred contributions from public corporations,<br />

effectively compelling parties to seek out illegal contributions (Waters,<br />

1994; Rhodes, 1997; for a dissent see Colazingari and Rose-Ackerman,<br />

1998: 459).<br />

Business politicians and their clients pr<strong>of</strong>ited personally from corruption,<br />

but through most <strong>of</strong> the First Republic corrupt revenues were used more to<br />

cement party hegemonies and elite networks than for self-enrichment (Hine,<br />

1995: 182). Proceeds were shared among the parties, and even at times with<br />

the Communists, in order to buy cooperation; party shares <strong>of</strong> major construction<br />

contracts were <strong>of</strong>ten negotiated in advance. Parties carved out<br />

bailiwicks in the public, private, and Italy’s large parastatal sectors roughly<br />

in proportion to their national power but also based on local and regional<br />

power bases (Golden, 2003: 189–202; Della Porta, 2004). Through a<br />

process <strong>of</strong> lottizzazione (‘‘allocation’’) jobs at many levels, including major<br />

policy and management positions, were divided up among parties (Hine,<br />

1995: 185; Bufacchi and Burgess, 1998:95).DellaPorta(2004) describes a<br />

similar partitizzazione (partitioning) process for appointments in the public<br />

bureaucracy that extended party-based clientelism.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!