28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

From analysis to reform 189<br />

In many ways expected contrasts did emerge. The Influence Market<br />

group has corruption issues that inhibit political competition and undermine<br />

the credibility and effectiveness <strong>of</strong> democratic processes, a fact that<br />

one-dimensional corruption indices underemphasize. Connections<br />

between wealth and power can be a systemic problem even when the<br />

giving and getting are legal and publicly disclosed. More important,<br />

however, is that Influence Market countries, while influential in shaping<br />

international reform agendas, differ qualitatively from others. Elite Cartel<br />

countries generally have institutions <strong>of</strong> only middling strength, and<br />

behind a façade <strong>of</strong> political competition elite hegemony is the rule.<br />

Parties colonize the bureaucracy, colluding to freeze out prospective<br />

competitors. Oligarch and Clan countries have weaker institutions still;<br />

much power resides in the hands <strong>of</strong> contending elites who are backed by<br />

personal networks spanning politics and the economy, state domains and<br />

private interests. So insecure is the situation that corruption is linked to<br />

violence in ways that have few parallels in Elite Cartel cases and virtually<br />

none in Influence Markets. Official Mogul cases, finally, stand influence<br />

markets on their heads: <strong>of</strong>ficial power, not wealth, drives most corrupt<br />

activities, as <strong>of</strong>ficials reach out and plunder the economy; quid pro quo<br />

exchanges occur but the biggest cases are little more than theft. The tax<br />

and duty-avoidance schemes <strong>of</strong> China, the Philippine oligarchs whose<br />

personal networks extend deep into the state and economy, and the<br />

politician–chaebol alliances <strong>of</strong> Korea are not just ‘‘more corrupt’’ than<br />

the political contribution scandals <strong>of</strong> Influence Market countries; they<br />

embody different patterns <strong>of</strong> participation and institutions, and different<br />

sorts <strong>of</strong> connections between wealth and power.<br />

A focus on syndromes changes our view <strong>of</strong> regional issues. Speculation<br />

abounds over contrasts between ‘‘Asian’’ and ‘‘African’’ corruption, particularly<br />

given the widely divergent economic records <strong>of</strong> those regions.<br />

African states do tend to cluster in the Official Moguls group, but<br />

there are intriguing variations: Benin, for example, is an Oligarch and<br />

Clan case while Botswana falls among the Elite Cartels. We should be<br />

cautious in generalizing about ‘‘African corruption,’’ and at the very least<br />

must consider influences beyond the geographical and (<strong>of</strong>ten more<br />

assumed than demonstrated) cultural commonalities. Similarly, Asian<br />

states are included in all four groups, with Japan, Korea, the<br />

Philippines, and Indonesia illustrating major contrasts. It is difficult to<br />

claim that fast-growing Asian countries hit upon some variety <strong>of</strong> beneficial<br />

corruption for a thirty-year period when corruption problems differ<br />

as they do. We might better look at how their economies did or did not<br />

withstand its effects for a time – particularly, via policy and intra-elite<br />

political processes – and how those connections changed over time.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!