28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

144 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

8–10; appendices 1 and 2). Such figures are approximations at best, but if<br />

corruption did siphon <strong>of</strong>f 3–4 percent <strong>of</strong> GDP that, in most years, would<br />

be the difference between stagnation and solid growth. Such losses help<br />

perpetuate a weak and ineffective state, inhibit the rise <strong>of</strong> challengers to<br />

the oligarchs, and reflect massive transfers <strong>of</strong> wealth into the hands <strong>of</strong> a<br />

few families – and then, most likely, out <strong>of</strong> the country.<br />

Oligarch and Clan corruption in the Philippines is hardly a clone <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Russian model, but it is marked by a similar organization <strong>of</strong> power, and<br />

contention, among personalized followings that extends deep into an<br />

ineffective state. Formal moves to liberalize the economy have likely<br />

helped key families extend their empires – as did the end <strong>of</strong> the Marcos<br />

dictatorship – although as in Russia the real extent <strong>of</strong> liberalization in an<br />

economy so dominated by clans, connections, colonized public agencies,<br />

and occasional violence is open to question. Institution-building and<br />

anti-corruption efforts have had only indifferent success, and are unlikely<br />

to become much more effective as long as a few wealthy families and<br />

widespread poverty, rather than a truly open economy and an active civil<br />

society, dominate national life.<br />

Mexico: oligarchs in the making?<br />

Mexico’s presence as our final case in this category may be a bit surprising.<br />

As recently as the late 1980s Mexican corruption coexisted with –<br />

indeed, was integral to – an impressive (if stultifying) political stability.<br />

Presidents dominated political life; they had large secret funds at their<br />

personal disposal and the power to hand-pick their successors. They had<br />

ruled since 1929 through the venerable Institutional Revolutionary Party<br />

(Partido Revolucionario Institutional, or PRI), a near-monopoly party<br />

that was part political machine, part repository <strong>of</strong> nationalist ideology,<br />

but first and foremost a means <strong>of</strong> control and the nation’s strongest single<br />

institution. In many respects Mexico embodied the Elite Cartel<br />

syndrome.<br />

But lately there has been change. In 2000 the PRI suffered its first-ever<br />

defeat in a presidential election; for years before that, drug gangs and<br />

corrupt police had been undermining central authority in some states.<br />

Liberalization opened up some segments <strong>of</strong> the economy and made it<br />

more difficult for the PRI to monopolize opportunities; international and<br />

domestic pressures for reform, particularly after the deeply suspect presidential<br />

election <strong>of</strong> 1988 (Preston and Dillon, 2004), attacked the PRI’s<br />

dominance as well. The PRI’s loss in 2000 hardly changed Mexico from<br />

an Elite Cartel to an Oligarchs and Clans case by itself: just how much<br />

that election really changed remains an open question. But the erosion <strong>of</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!