28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Participation, institutions, and syndromes <strong>of</strong> corruption 45<br />

Unlike the Elite Cartel syndrome, in which relatively established elites<br />

collude within a moderately strong institutional framework, oligarchs are<br />

free agents unlikely to cooperate for long. These elites are oligarchs in the<br />

sense that much <strong>of</strong> the most significant competition takes place – <strong>of</strong>ten in<br />

intensely personal terms – among relatively few players. But they and<br />

their gains are insecure because <strong>of</strong> the pace and scope <strong>of</strong> change, the<br />

unstructured nature and sheer scale <strong>of</strong> the stakes <strong>of</strong> contention, and<br />

recurring violence. Weak institutions are a particular problem: inability<br />

to enforce contracts or defend property through courts and law enforcement<br />

increases the incentive to resort to violence (Varese, 2001), making<br />

police and military muscle all the more marketable – and leading, in the<br />

worst cases, to reliance upon mafiyas or private armies. Scott (1972) and<br />

Knack and Keefer (1995) have pointed out that insecure elites will be<br />

particularly rapacious.<br />

As in the Elite Cartel syndrome, corruption will take place in pursuit <strong>of</strong><br />

both political and economic stakes, and will focus only partially upon<br />

formal roles and policy processes. But in an Oligarchs and Clans situation<br />

it may be difficult to say just what is public and what is private, who is a<br />

politician and who is an entrepreneur, or even who is clearly corrupt and<br />

who is an innovator. State <strong>of</strong>ficials and civil society will be ill-equipped to<br />

resist or check abuses. The former will have few effective powers and will<br />

be exposed to illicit pressures from within their agencies and without; the<br />

latter, particularly in post-transition states, will likely be weak and<br />

divided, its potential leaders intimidated or compromised. Those parts<br />

<strong>of</strong> the news media not dominated by oligarchs themselves may well lack<br />

the independence and resources needed to be effective watchdogs.<br />

There is considerable political competition in this type <strong>of</strong> case, but it<br />

can be unpredictable and may have shallow social roots. Contending<br />

oligarchs building mass followings will find material rewards valuable<br />

but difficult to come by; followers, for their part, will have many political<br />

options. Political factions will thus be unstable and poorly disciplined.<br />

Leaders, needing to pay for support again and again, will exploit any<br />

fragments <strong>of</strong> government authority that may come to hand. Business<br />

people may spend large sums for influence but get little from politicians<br />

who cannot ‘‘deliver.’’ Where elections are rigged and political competition<br />

unstructured and personal, reform-minded voters will find it difficult<br />

to oust the corrupt or to reward good government. Anti-corruption efforts<br />

in this setting will <strong>of</strong>ten be smokescreens for continued abuse or ways to<br />

put key competitors behind bars. Privatization can become a legalized<br />

carve-up <strong>of</strong> state resources or outright theft; regulatory and legal functions<br />

will not only be moneymakers for poorly paid <strong>of</strong>ficials, but may also be<br />

hijacked by oligarchs. Tax collections and payments are likely to be

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!