28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Elite Cartels 107<br />

and charities. During the 1980s and early 1990s, such contributions ran<br />

as large as 22 percent <strong>of</strong> net pr<strong>of</strong>its (Woo, 1991: 9). This immense cash<br />

flow helped maintain party and legislative organizations and rewarded<br />

key bureaucrats and military figures for their loyalty. A significant portion<br />

also underwrote the cost <strong>of</strong> huwo˘nhoe or ‘‘personal vote’’ practices<br />

(Kang, 2002a: 99) – gift-giving and vote-buying similar to those seen in<br />

Japan (Park Byeog-Seog, 1995: 168–172 describes a typical National<br />

Assemblyman’s political income and outlays). Some money stayed in<br />

the pockets <strong>of</strong> top politicians, although in the Park years it seems personal<br />

enrichment was secondary to building an elite network strong enough to<br />

hold power and to pursue growth (Kang, 2002a). Later, as democratization<br />

proceeded, some <strong>of</strong> the funds were slipped to opposition parties and<br />

leaders in order to keep them compliant (Pye, 1997: 220). In return for<br />

their money chaebols got access to capital and foreign exchange on preferential<br />

terms, light or non-existent regulation, and labor peace guaranteed<br />

by state repression. Until 1993 assets and property could be held<br />

under fictitious names or those <strong>of</strong> relatives, and money borrowed at<br />

preferential government interest rates could be re-lent at much higher<br />

rates. Favored chaebols pursued their own collusive economic practices<br />

such as underwriting each others’ debts (Beck, 1998). These exchanges<br />

took place within political and business strata smaller and more tight-knit<br />

than Japan’s; moreover, as Khan (2002: 480) notes, given the weakness <strong>of</strong><br />

civil society there was no need to share the spoils with ‘‘intermediary<br />

classes,’’ as was the case for many <strong>of</strong> the business-political networks<br />

<strong>of</strong> South Asia.<br />

The resulting Elite Cartel was a device <strong>of</strong> political control. Chaebol<br />

leaders who did not ‘‘contribute’’ – or, later on, those who showed signs <strong>of</strong><br />

political independence – not only had to seek credit on the far more<br />

expensive ‘‘curb market,’’ but also found themselves targets for hostile<br />

and arbitrary bureaucratic and legal proceedings. Business failure was a<br />

real possibility for those who fell out <strong>of</strong> favor. Whether by calculation or as<br />

a byproduct <strong>of</strong> political control and predictability – there is disagreement<br />

on this point – elite networks built partly on corruption also proved very<br />

effective at producing economic growth (Woo, 1991). Park rewarded<br />

development ‘‘winners,’’ making productivity and export growth important<br />

criteria for admission to the cartel.<br />

<strong>Corruption</strong> at work: major cases<br />

During his presidency Park Chung Hee raised large sums for his<br />

Democratic Republican Party’s operations and vote-buying (estimated<br />

to have cost $40 million in the 1967 campaign). DRP <strong>of</strong>ficials cultivated

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!