28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Influence Markets 81<br />

political parties dominated by a unified LDP, built out <strong>of</strong> formerly<br />

squabbling parties on the right, and including a unified (if much less<br />

effective) socialist opposition (Johnson, 1995: 214; Mitchell, 1996: xvi,<br />

109). The other is the ‘‘1941 system’’ <strong>of</strong> ‘‘bureaucracy-led industrial<br />

cooperation’’ (Johnson, 1982; Johnson, 1995: 226) dominated by prestigious,<br />

remote, highly able <strong>of</strong>ficials – a system that not only survived war,<br />

devastation, and reconstruction but also guided Japan’s emergence as a<br />

world economic power. The 1941 system made bureaucratic access and<br />

influence essential, while the 1955 system turned them into marketable<br />

political commodities. Together the 1955 system overlaid on the 1941<br />

allowed top politicians with bureaucratic connections to <strong>of</strong>fer credible<br />

commitments (Woodall, 1996: 20; Pascha, 1999: 10).<br />

The strength <strong>of</strong> bureaucratic institutions raised the ante – important<br />

decisions were made by high-status bureaucrats who followed through<br />

with great efficiency. A lack <strong>of</strong> access could mean not even being invited<br />

to bid on construction contracts, for example, or – for an aspiring local<br />

politician – not being able to take credit for projects or subsidies in a<br />

constituency. Trading in influence at a high level required a zoku<br />

(Johnson, 1995: 209–210; Blechinger, 2000) – a network or political<br />

tribe. A zoku linked Diet members sharing an interest in a particular<br />

kind <strong>of</strong> policy or sector <strong>of</strong> the economy to businesses and bureaucrats;<br />

some zoku members became virtual industry spokespersons (Blechinger,<br />

2000: 3).<br />

If the LDP held a near-monopoly, why was electoral politics so expensive?<br />

The answer has to do with both factionalism and the way Diet<br />

members were elected before 1994 (Christensen, 1996; Seligmann,<br />

1997). Most districts elected between two and six Diet members on a<br />

ballot on which parties did not designate an <strong>of</strong>ficial list <strong>of</strong> candidates. Real<br />

political influence depended upon being an LDP Diet member, but<br />

various factions’ candidates had to run against each other. Unable to<br />

differentiate themselves on policy issues, candidates had to buy electoral<br />

support. This they did by attending weddings, funerals, and other family<br />

occasions (or sending one <strong>of</strong> their dozen or more local agents to such<br />

affairs) and giving cash, <strong>of</strong>ten enclosed in an ornate gift card, to those<br />

involved (Pharr, 2005). Over time politicians built koenkai – local support<br />

networks <strong>of</strong> people sharing a recreational or cultural interest as well as a<br />

political commitment – through such contributions. One ‘‘W. T.,’’ a<br />

rank-and-file Lower House member, reported in 1976 that he gave out<br />

ninety-three such gifts in a typical month, the costs <strong>of</strong> which could easily<br />

exceed $1 million annually (Iga and Auerbach, 1977). Finding money on<br />

that scale meant backing an LDP faction leader whose prestige within the<br />

party was enhanced, in turn, by a large and active following. ‘‘Money

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!