28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

20 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

A similar outlook is reflected in TI’s best-known publication – the<br />

<strong>Corruption</strong> Perceptions Index (CPI). 1 The CPI is an annual ‘‘poll <strong>of</strong><br />

polls’’ in which results from varying numbers <strong>of</strong> surveys are averaged<br />

into scores for well over 100 countries, rating the extent to which they<br />

are seen as corrupt. Several <strong>of</strong> those component surveys specifically ask<br />

respondents to judge the extent <strong>of</strong> bribery, or <strong>of</strong> demands for bribes, in a<br />

country. Others sample international or domestic business people; some<br />

ask recipients the extent to which corruption harms the business environment,<br />

again framing the corruption issue in terms <strong>of</strong> bribery, business,<br />

and markets. CPI scores, like all other single-score country-level indicators,<br />

reduce potential qualitative differences to matters <strong>of</strong> degree while<br />

obscuring contrasts within societies (Khan and Sundaram, 2000: 9–10;<br />

Johnston, 2001a).<br />

What is wrong with this picture? Certainly not that these reports or the<br />

CPI draw upon bad ideas; nor is it that every case or country requires a<br />

unique policy or theory (although understanding the significance <strong>of</strong> what<br />

they have in common would seem to require more attention to contrasting<br />

cases). In some cases the organizations sponsoring these documents<br />

are restricted as to the in-country issues they may address. On the plus<br />

side, USAID has amassed significant anti-corruption capacity, and the<br />

OECD Anti-Bribery Treaty is a landmark achievement. The CPI, like TI<br />

and its many national chapters, has helped make corruption a priority<br />

issue in places where those in power would rather it be ignored. TI<br />

carefully documents the sources and methodology <strong>of</strong> the CPI 2<br />

(Lambsdorff, 1999), is candid about the index’s limitations, and in any<br />

event is not responsible for the ways the data are used by others. CPI<br />

results do fit in expected ways with other development measures, giving<br />

them significant construct validity, and there is little reason to think that<br />

the overall rankings are radically wrong. Indeed, I will make limited use <strong>of</strong><br />

the CPI later on in this book.<br />

The problems, instead, are those <strong>of</strong> worldview and analysis. As the<br />

overall emphasis on international business might lead us to expect, ‘‘corruption’’<br />

is too <strong>of</strong>ten treated as a synonym for ‘‘bribery’’ – in effect, as a<br />

particular kind <strong>of</strong> quid pro quo set apart by its illegitimate nature but<br />

otherwise open to analysis as just another process <strong>of</strong> exchange. Bribery,<br />

particularly when viewed broadly enough to include extortion (where an<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficial demands payment), probably is the most common form <strong>of</strong> corruption;<br />

it is certainly the easiest kind to model. But nepotism, <strong>of</strong>ficial<br />

theft and fraud, and conflict-<strong>of</strong>-interest problems, for example, do not fit<br />

1 Available at http://www.transparency.org/cpi/.<br />

2 See http://www.transparency.org/cpi/index.html#cpi.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!