28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

190 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

Other contrasts that did, and did not, emerge raise intriguing questions.<br />

Chapters 6 and 7 develop ideas about how and why the corruption<br />

problems <strong>of</strong> China and Russia differ. But many analysts <strong>of</strong> East Asia will<br />

be surprised (and perhaps less than persuaded!) that Japan and Korea are<br />

in different categories. Mexico’s presence in a group with Russia and the<br />

Philippines may draw objections, particularly considering how recently<br />

we might have called it an Elite Cartel case. Patrimonialism and clientelism<br />

are sometimes treated as distinctive syndromes in their own right; in<br />

my schema the former is found in both the Oligarchs and Clans and the<br />

Official Moguls groups, while clientelism is found in various forms there<br />

and in Elite Cartel cases too. But a focus only on techniques <strong>of</strong> corruption<br />

might obscure important underlying factors: clientelism and patronage in<br />

Korea, the Philippines, and Kenya, for example, involve differing kinds <strong>of</strong><br />

participants, and have contrasting consequences, reflecting (I argue)<br />

systemic contrasts.<br />

Another issue is that <strong>of</strong> contrasts within groups. To put two countries<br />

into the same cluster is not to say that their corruption is identical in every<br />

respect, as the relatively loose distribution <strong>of</strong> the Official Moguls group in<br />

figure 3.4 suggests. Elite Cartel corruption preserved a political stalemate<br />

in Italy while, in Botswana, it helped a modernizing traditional elite make<br />

policy credible enough to launch sustained growth. Italy experienced<br />

widespread colonization <strong>of</strong> the economy and state apparatus by major<br />

parties, while Botswana’s most important cases were focused upon specific<br />

bodies such as development banks and functions like housing construction<br />

(Frimpong, 1997). In both cases elites used corrupt incentives<br />

to defend their hegemonies, enrich themselves, and see <strong>of</strong>f potential<br />

competition, but Botswana is a small society with an elite to match, had<br />

one dominant party, and did not have Italy’s mature economy, large state<br />

sector, and overblown bureaucracy. Their Elite Cartel corruption reflects<br />

differences, therefore, but the comparison is still more informative than<br />

any blanket claim that either country is ‘‘more corrupt’’ than the other.<br />

Contrasts within groups become greater as we move from Influence<br />

Markets toward Official Moguls. In one way that is not surprising: affluent<br />

market democracies resemble each other in many ways, and it would<br />

be surprising if their corruption problems did not have important commonalities<br />

too. As we move to the other groups, however, institutions<br />

become weaker, climates <strong>of</strong> political and economic opportunities become<br />

more diverse and changeable, and the risks involved in corrupt deals<br />

become more unpredictable. Like Tolstoy’s happy and unhappy families,<br />

advanced political and economic systems tend to be advanced in similar<br />

ways, while weaker ones can have problems that are diverse and very<br />

much their own. In the former, impersonal laws and institutions are

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!