28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

22 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

center stage. Enhancing state capacity is now a top priority for institutions<br />

such as the World Bank (see, for example, Levy and Kpundeh, 2004).<br />

Agencies such as USAID are taking a more nuanced view <strong>of</strong> corruption as<br />

a problem embedded in social contexts, and are working on ways to<br />

distinguish among differing varieties. Still, interests and institutions primarily<br />

concerned with economic development will continue to set the<br />

anti-corruption agenda for some time to come. To make that agenda<br />

more responsive to the diversity and complexity <strong>of</strong> corruption we need to<br />

understand underlying causes <strong>of</strong> corruption and how they vary among the<br />

world’s societies. Those contrasts are <strong>of</strong> more than theoretical interest: in<br />

rapidly changing societies they make for qualitatively different development<br />

and corruption problems, not just differences in amounts.<br />

Change from within<br />

Years ago Denison Rustow (1970: 341–350; see also Anderson, 1999)<br />

pointed out that the factors that sustain democracy where it is strong –<br />

literacy, affluence, multiparty politics, a middle class – are not necessarily<br />

the same as those that brought it into being to begin with. He argued<br />

that democracy grew out <strong>of</strong> ‘‘prolonged and inconclusive political<br />

struggle ... [T]he protagonists must represent well-entrenched forces<br />

... and the issues must have pr<strong>of</strong>ound meaning to them’’ (Rustow,<br />

1970: 352). In those struggles, ‘‘Democracy was not the original or<br />

primary aim; it was sought as a means to some other end or it came as a<br />

fortuitous byproduct <strong>of</strong> the struggle’’ (ibid.: 353). Much the same is true<br />

<strong>of</strong> reform. Checks and balances, accountable leaders, liberal markets,<br />

competitive elections, and administrative transparency do much to control<br />

corruption in countries where it is the exception rather than the rule,<br />

and where they enjoy broad-based legitimacy. It does not follow, however,<br />

that the absence <strong>of</strong> such factors is what explains corruption where it is<br />

extensive, nor that putting them in place will control the problem.<br />

Historically, many societies reduced corruption in the course <strong>of</strong> contending<br />

over other, more basic issues <strong>of</strong> power and justice (Roberts, 1966;<br />

Johnston, 1993). Checks against various abuses were not so much<br />

schemes for good governance as political settlements – rules that contending<br />

interests could live with and could enforce by political means,<br />

allowing them to pursue their own interests while protecting themselves<br />

against predation by others. The institutions and norms <strong>of</strong> lowcorruption<br />

countries not only shape political and economic participation;<br />

in a long-term sense they are also the products <strong>of</strong> such participation. They<br />

ratify and enforce underlying settlements regarding the uses, and limits,<br />

<strong>of</strong> wealth and power. They were created and continue to work not just

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!