28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Influence Markets 71<br />

risk may be extortion by top legislative leaders; in recent years their<br />

power to rewrite bills late in the lawmaking process has grown significantly<br />

(Sinclair, 2000).<br />

Scholars have found little clear evidence that contributions buy rollcall<br />

votes (Snyder, 1992; Wright,1996; Wawro,2001). This may seem<br />

counterintuitive in light <strong>of</strong> cases such as the ‘‘bankruptcy reform’’ bills<br />

that followed a campaign marked by unusually large donations by<br />

banking PACs (Opensecrets.org, 2001), or pharmaceutical PACs’ contributions<br />

preceding the Medicare prescription drug legislation <strong>of</strong> 2003<br />

(Opensecrets.org, 2004a; Opensecrets.org, 2004b). But to attribute the<br />

legislation solely to contributions is to ignore wider political dynamics.<br />

In the bankruptcy case a pro-business Republican administration had<br />

taken <strong>of</strong>fice and Republicans held majorities in both houses.<br />

Prescription drug legislation treats the pharmaceutical industry very<br />

well indeed, but senior-citizen groups were powerful advocates too. In<br />

both cases opposition was weak and poorly organized. Contributors<br />

have more clout at less visible levels – for example, as subcommittees<br />

mark up bills, and as politicians interact informally among themselves<br />

and with other <strong>of</strong>ficials on small policy details about which neither the<br />

legislator nor constituents have strong sentiments (Etzioni, 1984: 9;<br />

Denzau and Munger, 1986; Gierzynski, 2000: 9;Levine,2004). But<br />

opportunities to provide such services arise only from time to time.<br />

Many groups give to candidates and <strong>of</strong>ficials who are receptive to their<br />

interests to begin with; while a representative <strong>of</strong> a dairy-farming district<br />

may receive money from dairy PACs he or she has sound electoral<br />

reasons to support their interests anyway. Conversely, many wellconnected<br />

interests are not so much seeking change as hoping to prevent<br />

it, and it is impossible to identify things that did not happen because <strong>of</strong><br />

donations. Wealth interests have always been powerful in American<br />

politics, and contributions are made with expectations that ordinary<br />

citizens are unlikely to have. But those interests would be powerful<br />

under any system <strong>of</strong> campaign finance we might imagine, and their<br />

ability to mobilize large contributions is at least as much a result <strong>of</strong><br />

their power as its cause.<br />

Lobbyists, contributors, and candidates generally agree that while<br />

donations do not buy legislative votes they do buy access – the opportunity<br />

to make a case on a given issue. Access is limited and does not guarantee<br />

favorable outcomes, but little can be accomplished without it. That is why<br />

it is worth paying for. Still, the market for access raises questions about<br />

the vitality <strong>of</strong> politics: a pervasive concern with fundraising can divert<br />

attention from groups and issues, and from the constituency work, that<br />

should be top priorities. The cumulative effects <strong>of</strong> spending most <strong>of</strong> one’s

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!