28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

194 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

qualitative and quantitative. But might we merely have rediscovered the<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> increasing amounts <strong>of</strong> corruption? The question is a serious one,<br />

but for several reasons I argue that the answer is no. For one thing, the<br />

corruption indices used in the plots in chapter 3 – which, it is worth<br />

repeating, were not used in defining the four groups – are open to considerable<br />

doubt on grounds <strong>of</strong> validity and, to a lesser extent, reliability<br />

(Johnston, 2001a). Perception-based indices emphasizing high-level<br />

bribery likely exaggerate overall differences between affluent market<br />

democracies and societies like Russia, Kenya, and Indonesia. Even if<br />

not, ‘‘more corruption’’ can mean many different things – frequent<br />

cases, high-level involvement, major political or economic costs, links to<br />

violence – involving a range <strong>of</strong> possible stakes and participants, as our case<br />

studies have shown.<br />

Moreover, to suggest that amounts <strong>of</strong> corruption account for the sorts<br />

<strong>of</strong> contrasts on view in our case studies is to put an immense explanatory<br />

burden on one factor. Those contrasts are multidimensional and exist on<br />

several levels, ranging from attitudes to politics and social trust to behavior<br />

such as theft and violence to factors such as the security <strong>of</strong> property<br />

and strength <strong>of</strong> civil society; it seems unlikely that they are explained by<br />

more or less <strong>of</strong> any one thing. Further, it is not obvious that corruption by<br />

itself explains as many development problems as we are sometimes told it<br />

does. It is embedded in, and interacts with, complex processes <strong>of</strong> change –<br />

indeed, it is more likely symptomatic <strong>of</strong> such factors than their cause.<br />

<strong>Corruption</strong> is an attractive ex post explanation for poverty (Sindzingre,<br />

2005) and political pathologies, particularly from the consensus view <strong>of</strong><br />

corruption as both cause and effect <strong>of</strong> difficulties in economic liberalization.<br />

But can we really say, with respect to any <strong>of</strong> the cases discussed<br />

here, that reducing corruption by X would yield Y amount <strong>of</strong> additional<br />

growth or Z improvement in democracy? Making the systemic changes<br />

required to check corruption would likely pay major economic and<br />

democratic dividends, but that just brings us back to the question <strong>of</strong><br />

what contrasting societies’ corruption problems, and their underlying<br />

causes, might be.<br />

The activities we see in the four groups – ‘‘money politics,’’ complex<br />

exchanges <strong>of</strong> corrupt incentives networking diverse elites, economic and<br />

political empire-building by oligarchs, and outright exploitation by<br />

powerful political figures and their protégés – differ from each other in<br />

important respects. Further, the scatter plots in chapter 3 suggest a<br />

discontinuous pattern: most Influence Market and Elite Cartel cases<br />

have high development scores, despite widely varying apparent amounts<br />

<strong>of</strong> corruption, while Oligarch and Clan and Official Mogul cases exhibit<br />

widely divergent levels <strong>of</strong> development despite comparably high

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!