28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Official Moguls 159<br />

<strong>of</strong> Suharto in 1998, but as we shall see it is hardly a sound democracy yet.<br />

China and Kenya have moved toward the market – China, dramatically –<br />

in terms <strong>of</strong> economic policy; Indonesia has been a market economy for<br />

some time but has become somewhat less open, to judge by the data, <strong>of</strong><br />

late, perhaps because <strong>of</strong> disruptions following the fall <strong>of</strong> Suharto. All<br />

remain relatively poor countries overall, and all but China fall below the<br />

median on the UNDP Human Development Index. China has experienced<br />

dramatic economic growth for the past generation; Indonesia’s<br />

generation <strong>of</strong> rapid but unequal economic expansion was halted for<br />

several years by the events <strong>of</strong> 1998. In all three countries <strong>of</strong>ficial institutions<br />

are weak and governance is ineffective. Property rights are not very<br />

secure, and corruption-control ratings fall well below the 98-nation<br />

median. These states are more interventionist than the three Oligarch<br />

and Clan cases in the previous chapter, yet Government Effectiveness<br />

and Regulatory Quality ratings range from middling to very weak. Finally,<br />

the impunity that characterizes Official Mogul corruption is reflected in<br />

these countries’ very low ratings for Voice and Accountability – scores that<br />

in the case <strong>of</strong> Indonesia put rising Polity scores into a sobering context.<br />

China: riding the tiger – for now 1<br />

<strong>Corruption</strong> is nothing new in China: reports <strong>of</strong> bribery, sometimes involving<br />

ambitious young men seeking to evade the rigorous examinations for<br />

<strong>of</strong>fic ial app ointm ents, date back m any centu ries (Liu , 1979 1978, ; Kiser<br />

and Tong, 1992; Reed, 2000). Local bribery and extortion have been<br />

longstanding themes too, their seriousness varying with the ability <strong>of</strong><br />

central government to exercise effective power. In the twentieth century<br />

demands for <strong>of</strong>ficial payments were common under Nationalist rule, a<br />

factor intensifying opposition to that regime.<br />

When the People’s Republic was proclaimed in October, 1949, eradicating<br />

past corruption was an early priority. Still, in the years before the<br />

death <strong>of</strong> Mao Zedong in 1976 and the launch <strong>of</strong> market-oriented policies<br />

in 1978, corruption was a continuing problem (Liu, 1983, 1990; Baum,<br />

1991; Kung and Gillette, 1993; Lo, 1993; Goodman, 1994; Gong, 1994,<br />

2002; Kwong, 1997; Bo, 2000; Fabre, 2001; Li, Smyth, and Yao, 2002;<br />

Sun, 2004). Favoritism was common; production was <strong>of</strong>ten falsely<br />

reported (Kwong, 1997: 111), but that served less to enrich anyone<br />

than as a way to avoid punishments for failing to meet the plans.<br />

<strong>Corruption</strong> for monetary gain was frequent but generally controlled in<br />

1 Sections <strong>of</strong> this discussion draw upon Hao and Johnston, 2002. I gratefully acknowledge<br />

Yufan Hao’s analytical contributions, translations, and wise advice.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!