28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

The international setting 21<br />

the bribery model well. In some corrupt exchanges, such as patronage<br />

and nepotism, considerable time may elapse between receiving the quid<br />

and repaying the quo, and the exchange may be conditioned by many<br />

factors other than immediate gain (Johnston, 1979). In practice quid and<br />

quo may be difficult to link and compare. In other cases, such as ‘‘constituent<br />

service’’ by legislators, illicit activities may be all but impossible to<br />

distinguish from legitimate ones, and corruption may lie not in an<br />

exchange but in cumulative effects upon the quality <strong>of</strong> political processes<br />

(Thompson, 1995; Mor<strong>of</strong>f, 2002). Still other varieties – corruptionviolence<br />

linkages, electoral fraud, embezzlement, or using <strong>of</strong>ficial resources<br />

for under-the-table business – are not exchanges at all. Political corruption<br />

is generally underemphasized compared to bureaucratic varieties.<br />

Other problems are evident at the level <strong>of</strong> corruption control. The<br />

political risks <strong>of</strong> confronting corruption and the collective-action problems<br />

inherent in mobilizing citizens to fight it (Johnston and<br />

Kpundeh, 2002) are too <strong>of</strong>ten reduced to calls for ‘‘political will.’’ Most<br />

consensus reforms amount to recommendations that developing societies<br />

emulate laws and institutions found in advanced societies; countermeasures<br />

are generally seen as ends in themselves, with little attention paid to<br />

how they originated and won support in societies where they are now in<br />

place. Stronger fiscal and managerial controls, greater transparency and<br />

accountability, monitoring by an independent judiciary and free news<br />

media, greater competition in politics and the economy, and a stronger<br />

civil society – to name some frequent recommendations – do help check<br />

corruption in many societies. But they did not emerge from nowhere;<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten, in fact, they were the results <strong>of</strong> democratization and political contention,<br />

and were devised by groups seeking to protect themselves rather<br />

than as plans for ‘‘good governance’’ in society at large. To be effective<br />

they require continued support from significant interests in society and<br />

legitimacy with respect to basic social values. Where anti-corruption<br />

forces are new such social support may be weak, or may need time to<br />

gather strength. Reforms, even when technically sound, can do more<br />

harm than good if they lack key resources and social backing: as we<br />

shall see, the premature implementation <strong>of</strong> competitive elections during<br />

the 1990s arguably made corruption more rapacious in Kenya and<br />

Indonesia.<br />

The analytical and policy trends outlined here extend across a range <strong>of</strong><br />

institutions and interests, and for each statement I have made there are <strong>of</strong><br />

course exceptions. Moreover, there are signs <strong>of</strong> change: by the late 1990s<br />

the value <strong>of</strong> institutions for sustaining and restraining liberalized economic<br />

and political processes was once again widely acknowledged, after<br />

fifteen years during which economic liberalization stood nearly alone at

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!