28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

86 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

Influence market corruption: more than meets the eye<br />

Political contributions and influence processes are not inherently corrupt,<br />

but they pose major questions about relationships between wealth and<br />

power in democracies. Most Influence Market societies have reached<br />

legal and political accommodations that check the worst excesses while<br />

not greatly restraining political and economic elites; still, many citizens <strong>of</strong><br />

those societies regard ‘‘money politics’’ as a broadly corrupting influence.<br />

Clearly, established democracies have not solved the corruption problem<br />

despite <strong>of</strong>ten depicting their own systems as standards <strong>of</strong> reform. A more<br />

accurate statement would be that they have a syndrome <strong>of</strong> their own that<br />

is more threatening to the values and vitality <strong>of</strong> politics than to economic<br />

development, one likely to attract less attention from organizations and<br />

interests accustomed to thinking about the costs <strong>of</strong> corruption primarily<br />

in economic terms. It is still a syndrome that is worth considerable<br />

concern.<br />

The scope <strong>of</strong> Influence Market corruption is difficult to specify. Corrupt<br />

contributions and influence can be difficult to distinguish from legitimate<br />

varieties; costs are long-term, widely distributed, and take the form <strong>of</strong><br />

reduced vitality <strong>of</strong> electoral politics and quality <strong>of</strong> public policy, rather<br />

than damage done by a few specific deals. Wealth interests may have<br />

so much political clout that more extensive corruption is unnecessary;<br />

alternatively, they and their political clients may have become adept at<br />

covering their tracks or at putting an acceptable public face on activities.<br />

If either (or both) are true, Influence Market democracies will have<br />

legitimated, privatized, or decentralized connections between wealth and<br />

power that in other societies take on clearly corrupt forms. That point is<br />

relevant not only to the relatively favorable corruption scores most<br />

Influence Market countries receive, but also to the longer-term implications<br />

<strong>of</strong> viewing economic liberalization as an anti-corruption strategy.<br />

Possible economic effects are also hard to judge. We will never know<br />

whether these three economies might have grown faster, or in more equitable<br />

or desirable ways, without Influence Market corruption. Germany<br />

and Japan are finding it difficult to adapt to the new world economy, a<br />

problem that might be traceable in part to the role <strong>of</strong> Influence Markets in<br />

preempting political competition and change. Further, we should not<br />

forget corruption involved in the international dealings <strong>of</strong> corporations<br />

that call market democracies home. Such cases will emerge, in chapters<br />

to come, as problems in less-developed countries.<br />

Influence Market cases share many attributes, but they are far from<br />

identical. Economic and political participation factors specific to these<br />

countries introduce variations; so do institutions, including not just

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!