28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

From analysis to reform 219<br />

between the GDP-and-elections development agendas <strong>of</strong> the past generation,<br />

on the one hand, and the full scope <strong>of</strong> change needed to control<br />

corruption, and reasons for doing so, on the other. A society actively<br />

pursuing deep democratization and justice will still have corruption, and<br />

may have to live with upheavals, at least for a time. But over time it can<br />

develop a capacity for avoiding the worst dilemmas seen in our case<br />

studies – a capacity rooted not just in punishments and administrative<br />

procedures but in the vitality <strong>of</strong> society itself.<br />

Conclusion<br />

We have come a long way from a discussion <strong>of</strong> corruption and development<br />

in an era <strong>of</strong> liberalization and globalization to a consideration <strong>of</strong><br />

strategies for reform. All <strong>of</strong> these issues, however, have common dimensions<br />

<strong>of</strong> democracy, accountability, and justice, and unlike many other<br />

critics I believe most advocates <strong>of</strong> ‘‘consensus’’ policy are genuinely<br />

motivated by their understandings <strong>of</strong> those same issues. Still, those issues<br />

frame an urgent debate over the ways wealth and power can be pursued,<br />

used, and exchanged – a debate most notable by its absence in contemporary<br />

policymaking. And they are the reasons why corruption is worth<br />

our concern in the first place: all revolve around the fundamental right <strong>of</strong><br />

human beings to a good life and to participate in decisions affecting their<br />

lives. I have tried to show that those concerns are not only the ends, but<br />

also essential means, <strong>of</strong> reform.<br />

As noted at the outset the revival <strong>of</strong> interest in corruption has reflected<br />

interests and organizations central to globalization, and has been driven<br />

by a sense that corruption not only impedes economic growth and integration<br />

but is also on the rise. Those connections have been made in a<br />

narrow and technical way, for the most part: at the level <strong>of</strong> observed<br />

behavior, corruption was seen primarily as bribery, part and parcel <strong>of</strong><br />

imperfect or politically blocked processes <strong>of</strong> exchange. Politics and the<br />

state have been envisioned, at best, as technical facilitators <strong>of</strong> markets,<br />

and at worst as the essence <strong>of</strong> the corruption problem. Not surprisingly<br />

public institutions were for many years secondary concerns in most discussions<br />

<strong>of</strong> reform.<br />

Therein lies a less-recognized risk <strong>of</strong> the consensus liberalization<br />

agenda: we could conceivably minimize corruption – in a definitional<br />

sense at least – by doing away with public power and roles. But would we<br />

have reduced corruption in a real sense, or just have privatized it (Johnston,<br />

2001a)? And would we like the world that would result? In my view the<br />

economic liberalization <strong>of</strong> the past generation has, paradoxically, made<br />

clearer than ever the need for strong and accountable institutions that are

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!