28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

114 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

Competitive politics has raised the costs <strong>of</strong> campaigns, driving demands<br />

for cash upwards. Kang (2002b: 195) reports estimates <strong>of</strong> 200–300 billion<br />

won, or $266–400 million, for the total expenditures in the 1981 National<br />

Assembly election, compared to more than 1 trillion won (about $1.3<br />

billion) for the 1996 campaign; total presidential campaign expenditures<br />

were estimated at 443 billion won ($590 million) in 1987, and 2 trillion won<br />

($2.7 billion) in 1997. The 1997 presidential total is roughly on a par with<br />

all federal election expenditures in the United States – which has over five<br />

times Korea’s population – in 2000. Some <strong>of</strong> these increases reflect the<br />

growth <strong>of</strong> Korea’s economy and population, and inflation is a factor too.<br />

Moreover, not all <strong>of</strong> this money came from business; some was raised<br />

through legitimate contributions, and other funds have been corruptly<br />

diverted from the national budget over the years (Park Byeog-Seog,<br />

1995: 175–176). But pressure upon business for contributions has intensified<br />

(Moran, 1999: 573) and businesses will still pay to reduce political<br />

uncertainties (Root, 1996: 167–168).<br />

Can Elite Cartel corruption continue on such a scale? There are<br />

reasons to think it cannot. Lobbying activities recognizable in any democracy<br />

have become more common (Park Byeog-Seog, 1995: 183).<br />

As parties and civil society become stronger, political uncertainties may<br />

become more manageable: real competition would bring risk <strong>of</strong> defeat,<br />

but a strong electoral system would guarantee opportunities to win future<br />

elections. Democracy could weaken the force <strong>of</strong> clientelism (Kim Joongi,<br />

2002: 184–185) and clan ties may give way to more fluid political<br />

competition. Global competition and international pressures to improve<br />

both public- and private-sector governance may make chaebols less able<br />

to pay (and to conceal) the price <strong>of</strong> political influence, and the<br />

state less able to maintain politically protected lending markets and<br />

policy favors.<br />

If Elite Cartel corruption should break down, however, the alternative<br />

will not be no corruption. Korea might become more like Japan and other<br />

Influence Market societies. For that to happen institutions would have to<br />

continue to strengthen while the economic and political competition<br />

would need to become more predictable. Such trends seem likely and,<br />

in the case <strong>of</strong> institutional development, are already underway. But if<br />

those changes are derailed, key figures in a less-unified elite may turn to<br />

personal followings, influence within their own segments <strong>of</strong> the state and<br />

economy, and perhaps even violence to protect their interests. While that<br />

seems a less likely scenario, our case discussion <strong>of</strong> Mexico in chapter 6 will<br />

suggest that Elite Cartel corruption can change in some very worrisome<br />

ways. Governing Korea is a changed task early in the twenty-first century,<br />

but that does not mean it has become easy.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!