28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

202 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

by public opinion, ends up doing neither. Further, it does relatively little<br />

to curb the risk <strong>of</strong> extortion by secure multiterm incumbents. Refocusing<br />

political finance laws toward encouraging competition among distinct<br />

and separate parties – creating more single-member parliamentary constituencies<br />

to reduce party collusion, or encouraging varieties <strong>of</strong> proportional<br />

representation that avoid the Japanese pattern <strong>of</strong> competition<br />

within a dominant party – and creating ways and incentives to finance<br />

their activities in broad-based ways, would be positive changes. Making<br />

individual races more competitive, perhaps through subsidies to new<br />

parties and making it easier to challenge incumbents, could help check<br />

corruption indirectly through increased competition and mass participation.<br />

That there would be substantial resistance among the incumbents<br />

themselves who, after all, write the laws, is precisely the sort <strong>of</strong> issue that<br />

encourages public cynicism, and is a reflection <strong>of</strong> the competitive malaise<br />

found in the United States and other Influence Market systems.<br />

No single set <strong>of</strong> measures guarantees revived political competition and<br />

renewed public credibility, but fresh thinking is in order, and a number <strong>of</strong><br />

possibilities are available for experimentation. In two quite different<br />

American states – Maine and Arizona – ‘‘Clean Politics’’ initiatives providing<br />

the option <strong>of</strong> full public funding to candidates who first demonstrate<br />

reasonable levels <strong>of</strong> voter support have proven popular in their first<br />

few election cycles. Candidates wishing to run under the old rules <strong>of</strong><br />

private donations and disclosure are free to do so, but indications are<br />

that ‘‘Clean Politics’’ candidates enjoy some advantages in terms <strong>of</strong> public<br />

opinion (Common Cause, 1999). A different approach is a ‘‘blind trust’’<br />

system under which private contributions are made through a central<br />

clearinghouse and forwarded on to candidates and parties without indications<br />

<strong>of</strong> their sources. Records <strong>of</strong> contributions would be retained by<br />

that agency for legal purposes but not be made public; all contributors<br />

would have a cooling-<strong>of</strong>f period during which they could retract a contribution.<br />

The key idea <strong>of</strong> blind trusts – implemented in limited ways in<br />

South Korea and the United Kingdom, and receiving close examination<br />

in Chile – is not that the sources <strong>of</strong> funds are kept secret, but rather that<br />

they be unverifiable, thus weakening the leverage <strong>of</strong> contributors and<br />

unscrupulous candidates alike.<br />

Alternatively, matching-funds formulae could reward parties for registering<br />

voters and for increases in turnouts, or might generously augment<br />

small contributions while not matching larger ones. Setting incumbent<br />

opposition aside for one moment, we could even imagine a ‘‘tax’’ on very<br />

large contributions that would divert a percentage into a public-financing<br />

fund. The point is that there are many conceivable approaches to<br />

enhancing the public credibility <strong>of</strong> electoral politics, and even now-secure

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!