28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

100 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

global economic trends, were drying up the pool <strong>of</strong> patronage that had<br />

sustained corrupt networks (see also Guzzini, 1995). Party cashiers were<br />

demanding ever larger sums from business people who found it harder to<br />

pay, and all but the most prosperous began to drop out <strong>of</strong> the game. Most<br />

business people who talked to the judges were second-rank figures or<br />

lower (Golden, 2002: 49); the bribe-payer whose testimony started the<br />

tangentopoli avalanche ran a local cleaning service in Milan. The young<br />

judges’ new aggressiveness contributed to the collapse <strong>of</strong> a system that<br />

had been hollowed out over two decades.<br />

Holding the deals together<br />

Parties had been critical to Elite Cartel corruption not only because <strong>of</strong> the<br />

state benefits they could distribute, but also because they were the guarantors<br />

<strong>of</strong> the deals that built and sustained elite networks. Those networks<br />

were highly factionalized and contentious, but they shared an<br />

interest in retaining the political power that was the source <strong>of</strong> all good<br />

things. Collusion was sustained by corrupt deals. But given their illegality,<br />

and the low levels <strong>of</strong> trust that <strong>of</strong>ten existed among factions and their<br />

leaders, how could those deals be enforced?<br />

While corruption was scarcely a secret, the illusion <strong>of</strong> electoral competition<br />

was important, and the constitutional independence <strong>of</strong> the Italian<br />

judiciary meant that specific deals and spoils-sharing agreements had to<br />

be concealed. Pizzorno (1993) argues that the parties functioned much<br />

like credit bureaux, providing information on the dependability <strong>of</strong> various<br />

politicians and factions. They also enforced de facto codes <strong>of</strong> silence and<br />

honor; those who revealed abuses or failed to carry out their end <strong>of</strong> a deal<br />

could be dropped from the party list, cut out <strong>of</strong> the spoils, or handed over<br />

to the judiciary – the latter, perhaps, even doing the party’s image some<br />

good. Parties also negotiated the terms <strong>of</strong> lottizzazione and shares <strong>of</strong><br />

contracts, again reducing conflict and penalizing defectors. At times<br />

political notables were recruited, and paid, to serve as enforcers and<br />

monitors <strong>of</strong> corrupt agreements (Della Porta and Vannucci, 1999,<br />

2002: 723). In the south, the role <strong>of</strong> enforcer was <strong>of</strong>ten taken over by<br />

organized crime.<br />

Such machinations helped DC elites and their partners share the spoils<br />

and hold on to power, but they also diverted energy and resources from<br />

the parties’ broader political functions. Memberships declined; those<br />

who remained active did so for mercenary reasons, or out <strong>of</strong> loyalty to a<br />

patron, rather than to fight for a cause. The parties became less rooted in<br />

organic segments <strong>of</strong> society and on the left–right spectrum, and more like<br />

overlapping bands <strong>of</strong> business-politicians. In effect they became ‘‘cartel

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!