28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

52 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

rights, variables. Group 2 (N ¼ 21), including Argentina, Belgium, Chile,<br />

Italy, South Korea, Poland, Spain, and Zambia among others, is broadly<br />

democratic (and becoming somewhat more so), if not quite as highly<br />

rated as Group 1; similarly, the economies in this group are relatively<br />

liberalized but also becoming more so. New political and economic<br />

opportunities are likely emerging in these societies, but institution scores<br />

are lower than those for Group 1. Group 3 (N ¼ 30), exemplified inter alia<br />

by Albania, Colombia, Ecuador, Malaysia, Mexico, the Philippines,<br />

Russia, and Venezuela, is still democratizing as a whole. Economies in<br />

this group continue to liberalize too, and these changes have taken place in<br />

a setting <strong>of</strong> weak social/institutional capacity and somewhat uncertain<br />

property rights. Finally, Group 4 (N ¼ 29), which includes, for example,<br />

Algeria, Chad, China, Indonesia, Jordan, Nigeria, Syria, Tanzania, and<br />

Zimbabwe, is marked by rather rapid liberalization in both the political and<br />

economic arenas, but remains largely undemocratic and suffers from weak<br />

institutions. As the analysis <strong>of</strong> variance shows, the differences in variable<br />

scores defining these four clusters are statistically strongly significant.<br />

The cluster results correspond reasonably closely to the patterns<br />

proposed earlier, although statistical clustering does not mean we have<br />

‘‘discovered’’ these groups out in the world. Data limitations mean that<br />

many countries <strong>of</strong> interest could not be classified; further, mean polity<br />

scores for Group 3 show less change, and for Group 4, more change than<br />

we might have expected. Group 3, however, includes several transitional<br />

post-communist cases where rapid political liberalization came just<br />

before 1992, and Group 4, while less authoritarian in the aggregate by<br />

2000 than in 1992, remains on the undemocratic side <strong>of</strong> the scale.<br />

Do these groupings correspond to contrasts in corruption? The scatter<br />

plots in figures 3.1–3.4 suggest that they may. There is one plot for each<br />

group <strong>of</strong> countries, and axes are the same as in figure 2.1: HDI scores from<br />

the 2003 report, covering 2001, are plotted against ‘‘inverted’’ TI scores for<br />

2003. Earlier caveats about the TI index remain very much in force; the<br />

question at this point is only whether grouping countries by participation<br />

and institution measures begins to sort out some <strong>of</strong> the complexities we<br />

found when we looked behind the basic corruption–development connections<br />

that figure so strongly in the consensus view. Means for the four<br />

groups on those indices are presented following the plots.<br />

The plots and data are generally consistent with the idea <strong>of</strong> differing<br />

corruption–development connections among the four groups. Group 1<br />

countries (fig. 3.1) – most <strong>of</strong> them established market democracies –<br />

enjoy high levels <strong>of</strong> development and are perceived as having moderate<br />

to low amounts <strong>of</strong> corruption (though that notion will come in for critical<br />

examination in later chapters). Most Group 2 countries (fig. 3.2) are

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!