28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

96 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

The real political competition took place behind the party façade<br />

among political factions increasingly dominated by business politicians<br />

(Della Porta and Vannucci, 1999, 2002; Della Porta, 2004). The pre-<br />

1993 party-list system, in which voters expressed preferences among<br />

various candidates, exacerbated intra-party contention by forcing competition<br />

among politicians <strong>of</strong> the same party. Campaign finance was<br />

channeled through the parties legally and through faction leaders illicitly.<br />

Competing factions bought support with extensive local patronage<br />

(Moss, 1995; Golden, 2003: 198–204), further driving up the appetite<br />

for cash (Golden and Chang, 2001; Della Porta, 2004). Factions and the<br />

distribution <strong>of</strong> spoils extended across party lines (Della Porta, 2004)asa<br />

way <strong>of</strong> minimizing the risks <strong>of</strong> losing <strong>of</strong>fice. Left–right distinctions<br />

became mostly pro forma; broad policy initiatives were absent and<br />

would have had little credibility. Elections served to preserve the status<br />

quo and to define the parameters <strong>of</strong> the next rounds <strong>of</strong> lottizzazione,rather<br />

than to oust ineffective governments or reward success. At times, the DC<br />

coalition functioned almost as a national ‘‘super-party’’ (Della Porta and<br />

Vannucci, 2002:726).<br />

<strong>Corruption</strong> ultimately led to the downfall <strong>of</strong> the First Republic. But in<br />

other ways the elite linkages it reflected and sustained were the skeleton<br />

and nerves <strong>of</strong> the system. <strong>Corruption</strong> eased conflict, controlled the scope<br />

and risks <strong>of</strong> electoral competition, and made unworkable laws and agencies<br />

at least somewhat effective. It both thrived upon, and partially compensated<br />

for, the weakness <strong>of</strong> state institutions, political parties, and popular<br />

allegiances. Italians would have been better served by genuinely competitive<br />

parties rooted in real social interests, and by a less-politicized<br />

economy. But given the weakness <strong>of</strong> the state and the persistence <strong>of</strong><br />

factionalism it is unclear how real those alternatives were.<br />

Secret networks and failed reforms<br />

<strong>Corruption</strong> has long been a fact <strong>of</strong> Italian life (Waquet, 1996, discusses<br />

the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries; on corruption as a continuing<br />

presence in the post-World War Two era see Chang and Golden, 2004).<br />

The practices that ultimately led to tangentopoli and mani pulite, however,<br />

were <strong>of</strong> relatively recent origins. Much <strong>of</strong> the wrongdoing in the early<br />

First Republic was non-systematic and relatively modest in scale; one <strong>of</strong><br />

the most notable 1960s scandals revolved around the import and sale <strong>of</strong><br />

bananas, for example. Beginning with the ‘‘petrol scandal’’ <strong>of</strong> 1973,<br />

however, corruption grew dramatically in frequency and scope, and<br />

became more systematic (Hine, 1995: 185–186; Rhodes, 1997: 56;<br />

Della Porta and Vannucci, 1999; Golden and Chang, 2001: 595).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!