28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

From analysis to reform 199<br />

countermeasures (most <strong>of</strong> them familiar) appropriate to particular societies<br />

and implementing them in the proper sequence, and avoiding<br />

changes that do more harm than good. Implementing ‘‘best practices’’<br />

where institutions are weak and corrupt interests dominate may<br />

accomplish little. Lifting expectations but failing at reform wastes scarce<br />

opportunities and increases the difficulty <strong>of</strong> subsequent efforts. Longterm<br />

strategy requires careful thought about what is possible, <strong>of</strong>ten as<br />

intermediate steps. Building the institutional foundations and political<br />

constituencies reform measures require, enabling societies to withstand<br />

the corruption they experience, and shifting it over time toward less<br />

disruptive varieties are more appropriate goals, and more sustainable in<br />

the long run, than aiming directly at sizeable reductions in corruption.<br />

A developmental ideal<br />

If high-corruption societies should not simply emulate affluent market<br />

democracies or shoot for better scores on indices, what should they aim<br />

for? In chapter 2 I laid out a very general developmental ideal: a system<br />

in which political and economic participation are open, vigorous, and<br />

broadly in balance – in the sense that political actors do not dominate<br />

the economy, and vice versa – and where activity in both spheres is<br />

sustained and restrained by strong state, political, and social institutions.<br />

That ideal helped define our four corruption syndromes, but it<br />

may also be a kind <strong>of</strong> pole star for reform. Strong institutions and<br />

balanced participation enable societies to respond to corrupt activities<br />

more effectively. They provide non-corrupt economic and political<br />

alternatives for citizens and firms and enable them to defend their<br />

interests. <strong>Corruption</strong> would scarcely vanish in such a system, but if<br />

our analysis is correct it would occur in less disruptive forms. Further,<br />

to the extent that corruption actually is a consequence and cause <strong>of</strong><br />

incomplete liberalization, well-institutionalized, competitive politics<br />

and economies are less likely to be dominated by corrupt elites or<br />

those <strong>of</strong>fering cash to make things happen.<br />

At first glance that ideal may seem just another way <strong>of</strong> saying developing<br />

societies should emulate affluent market democracies, but it is not:<br />

advanced societies themselves fall short <strong>of</strong> the ideal, as witness their own<br />

corruption problems. Further, the ideal has several dimensions – institutions<br />

<strong>of</strong> several sorts and two diverse arenas <strong>of</strong> participation – making<br />

reform strongly path-dependent. Problems can arise in a number <strong>of</strong><br />

different combinations; the journey toward the goal will not run along a<br />

single dimension <strong>of</strong> less to more development, but will depend greatly<br />

upon a country’s particular array <strong>of</strong> difficulties. Official Mogul societies,

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!