28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

158 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

and face little legal or political constraint. Such uncoordinated monopolies,<br />

with no restraints upon the prices they exact, can choke <strong>of</strong>f whole<br />

streams <strong>of</strong> economic activity (Shleifer and Vishny, 1993); unpredictable<br />

corruption is likewise especially harmful to economic development<br />

(Campos, Lien, and Pradhan, 1999). Even where Official Mogul corruption<br />

coexists with rapid growth, as in China, it is difficult to argue that it is<br />

somehow beneficial for development: other effects can include inhibiting<br />

the national integration <strong>of</strong> markets; weakening secondary economic<br />

institutions, such as bond and equity markets, and the reality-testing<br />

and international integration functions they perform in a developing<br />

economy (Karmel, 1996); stunting the growth <strong>of</strong> civil society by choking<br />

<strong>of</strong>f its economic base and autonomy; and increased externalities such as<br />

environmental damage and social disruption.<br />

A lack <strong>of</strong> electoral opposition and legal accountability does not mean an<br />

absence <strong>of</strong> challenges, however. In a setting <strong>of</strong> weak institutions and<br />

significant social change top figures may face separatist movements,<br />

communal contention, personal rivals, or other forms <strong>of</strong> unrest. Any<br />

such insecurity encourages rapacious ‘‘hand over fist’’ corruption<br />

(Scott, 1972); so too, ironically, might poorly institutionalized efforts at<br />

democratization, as we shall see. The personal agendas <strong>of</strong> top leaders can<br />

thus make an immense difference: some may perceive threats to their<br />

rule, while others do not; some may tolerate or encourage corruption<br />

while others impose working limits upon exploitation, or even fight it.<br />

Not surprisingly, this group is marked by wide variation in corruption and<br />

development situations.<br />

Three cases<br />

In this chapter I consider three cases – the People’s Republic <strong>of</strong> China,<br />

Kenya under Daniel arap Moi, and Indonesia during and following the<br />

Suharto years – located in this category by the statistical analysis in<br />

chapter 3 and collectively illustrating the systemic corruption problems<br />

outlined above. All have experienced significant corruption; all have seen<br />

ambitious elites exploit economic opportunities while most citizens<br />

remain poor – at times, desperately so. None would qualify as a wellinstitutionalized<br />

democracy. All have relatively intrusive but ineffective<br />

states – arguably, a hallmark <strong>of</strong> Official Mogul abuses – and weak<br />

mechanisms <strong>of</strong> accountability. Consider the indicators presented in<br />

Table 7.1.<br />

China and Kenya broadly fit the Official Moguls pr<strong>of</strong>ile <strong>of</strong> weak<br />

institutions, expanding economic opportunities, and undemocratic<br />

politics. Indonesia’s Polity ratings improved markedly following the fall

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!