28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

14 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

A parallel argument can be made about markets: some transitional<br />

economies have experienced spectacular, if uneven, success (China<br />

and, more recently, India), or have at least sustained generally positive<br />

trends (Poland, Hungary, Chile, Botswana). But others have endured<br />

periods <strong>of</strong> chaos (Russia, post-1997 Indonesia), a drift backward toward<br />

illiberal practices (Belarus), or outright failure (Argentina and several<br />

African economies). In Brazil the election <strong>of</strong> President Lula da Silva<br />

in November, 2002, was widely judged a popular backlash against<br />

economic liberalization and its perceived social consequences. The<br />

Asian economic meltdown <strong>of</strong> the late 1990s, with its serious damage to<br />

emerging economies that had long been the envy <strong>of</strong> many other societies,<br />

raised further questions about corruption, markets, and the role <strong>of</strong><br />

the state.<br />

Advanced countries have their periods <strong>of</strong> political and economic difficulty,<br />

and they too experience corruption which, I will argue, is more<br />

serious than most corruption indices seem to suggest. There are poor<br />

democracies, such as India, and wealthy undemocratic societies such as<br />

Kuwait and Singapore. There are third-wave success stories too, such as<br />

Spain, Poland, and Chile. So the connections we will explore in this book<br />

are complicated, and the four syndromes <strong>of</strong> corruption I will propose are<br />

but a first step toward disentangling them and designing appropriate<br />

policy responses. Still, the optimism <strong>of</strong> the late 1980s and 1990s has<br />

given way to a more sober appreciation <strong>of</strong> the challenges <strong>of</strong> liberalization<br />

and development – and as optimism has cooled, the focus on corruption<br />

has intensified. The United States government, through its Millennium<br />

Challenge Accounts initiative, has made corruption and good government<br />

a priority issue affecting the way major development aid resources<br />

will be distributed and withheld. International anti-corruption<br />

agreements sponsored by the United Nations, the Organization for<br />

Economic Cooperation and Development, and the Organization<br />

<strong>of</strong> American States reflect similar commitments on an even broader<br />

scale. As we contemplate such initiatives, and as we reassess the effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> a generation <strong>of</strong> liberalization and deemphasis <strong>of</strong> the state, a clear<br />

understanding <strong>of</strong> the nature and origins <strong>of</strong> corruption has never been a<br />

higher priority.<br />

Too <strong>of</strong>ten in the policy debate, however, corruption has been seen as a<br />

generic problem. Its deeper origins, the ways it is embedded in political<br />

and economic processes, and its role as a symptom <strong>of</strong> diverse and problematical<br />

relationships between wealth and power, public and private<br />

interests, and state and society, are acknowledged but only poorly understood<br />

in depth. The institutions and norms <strong>of</strong> affluent market democracies<br />

are posited as the obvious goal <strong>of</strong> reform; as a result, reform

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!