28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Oligarchs and Clans 133<br />

After the fall: markets without order<br />

Early on, much post-Soviet corruption was straightforward: in a series <strong>of</strong><br />

smash-and-grab operations, members <strong>of</strong> the old nomenklatura laid claim<br />

to ‘‘their’’ industries, mines, and enterprises. Sometimes these moves<br />

were portrayed as privatizations (Varese, 1997: 591–592); other assets<br />

were simply stolen (Karklins, 2002: 25–27) and defended by mafiya<br />

muscle where necessary. Old enterprises, banks, and ministries were<br />

simply rebranded as private concerns, <strong>of</strong>ten with the same people in the<br />

same buildings continuing to run day-to-day affairs (Satter, 2003: 49). In<br />

a sense this first ‘‘un<strong>of</strong>ficial’’ round <strong>of</strong> privatization only ratified trends<br />

already taking place during the last years <strong>of</strong> communism. That meant,<br />

however, that the <strong>of</strong>ficial privatization efforts launched in 1992 encountered<br />

powerful entrenched interests (McFaul, 1995: 212, 224).<br />

Reformers could hardly take back the enterprises that the ‘‘red bureaucrats’’<br />

had seized, and they could make few credible promises to investors<br />

in <strong>of</strong>ficial privatizations. Indeed, later entrants <strong>of</strong>ten found it necessary to<br />

use corruption <strong>of</strong> their own to protect against predation by the early<br />

movers and their bureaucratic clients (Varese, 1997: 580). The resulting<br />

bidding war for <strong>of</strong>ficial influence seriously undermined the credibility <strong>of</strong><br />

state institutions just as <strong>of</strong>ficial privatizations were being launched.<br />

That process was supposed to take place in two phases. ‘‘Voucher<br />

privatization,’’ launched in October, 1992, gave each citizen a voucher,<br />

nominally valued at 10,000 Rubles, supposedly representing one share <strong>of</strong><br />

the nation’s industrial structure (Appel, 1997; Lavrentieva, 2002;<br />

Pribylovsky, 2003; Satter, 2003: 49–50). In theory vouchers created<br />

broad-based ownership and distributed wealth to those needing it most:<br />

as antiquated as Russian industry was, <strong>of</strong>ficials still believed the ‘‘true’’<br />

value <strong>of</strong> one share far exceeded 10,000 Rubles and that citizens would<br />

benefit from the difference. In practice, however, the system was poorly<br />

understood by citizens who were given little real information and had<br />

never experienced legitimate market interactions; converting vouchers<br />

into their theoretical full value was impossible. Many sold their vouchers<br />

to speculators for next to nothing or lost them in fraudulent ‘‘cooperative’’<br />

schemes. At the program’s end in 1994 <strong>of</strong>ficials claimed that the overwhelming<br />

majority <strong>of</strong> vouchers had been redeemed; actual benefits,<br />

however, flowed to very few.<br />

‘‘Money privatization’’ began in 1994. In this phase the goal was to<br />

auction <strong>of</strong>f state-owned assets, thereby attracting foreign investment and<br />

expertise, creating pr<strong>of</strong>itable enterprises owned by a range <strong>of</strong> competing<br />

interests, and earning major revenue for the state. The latter, in turn,<br />

would narrow public deficits, support the Ruble, and enable state

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!