28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Influence Markets 85<br />

nearly impossible. But that lack <strong>of</strong> accountability may have indirect<br />

economic costs to the extent that governments find it difficult (or unnecessary)<br />

to change policies in response to economic change (on Japan’s<br />

political and economic prospects see Mann and Sasaki, 2002; Katz,<br />

2003). As long as growth was rapid and living standards continued to<br />

rise, voters may have concluded that their bargain with the state, and with<br />

the LDP that mediated between it and society, was a good one. But as<br />

Japan’s economic tides have rolled out in the past decade resentment <strong>of</strong><br />

corruption has grown. Mitchell (1996: xvii, 157) is undoubtedly correct<br />

in arguing that genuine reform will require not just new electoral laws, but<br />

rather fundamental changes in relationships between wealth and power.<br />

The future <strong>of</strong> Japanese corruption is difficult to predict. Weaker factions<br />

and a more pluralistic pattern <strong>of</strong> influence within the LDP, enhanced interparty<br />

competition, and more decisive national elections could produce a<br />

more decentralized Influence Market – perhaps like that <strong>of</strong> the United<br />

States. The frequency <strong>of</strong> bribery and the amounts changing hands might<br />

remain high by American standards, but individual politicians – most<br />

with little bureaucratic clout to put on the market – running against real<br />

competitors from other parties in single-member districts would not<br />

command bribes on the scale seen before 1993. LDP and zoku membership<br />

would be less saleable assets. If people and businesses in Japan are now<br />

less dependent upon the state (Schoppa, 2001) that too might check<br />

Influence Market corruption. Japanese politics will remain factionalized,<br />

and the power <strong>of</strong> the central state bureaucracy will continue to be a fact <strong>of</strong><br />

life, but corruption may come to look more like that <strong>of</strong> other Influence<br />

Market countries (Cox, Rosenbluth, and Theis, 1999:56).<br />

But another, more pessimistic scenario is also possible. Mishima (1998)<br />

argues that the high status and remoteness <strong>of</strong> the bureaucracy helped<br />

‘‘discipline’’ policies during the LDP’s years <strong>of</strong> dominance, but notes that<br />

bureaucrats are now somewhat more accessible and ‘‘conciliatory’’ to the<br />

political world. As a consequence, Mishima argues, the bureaucracy has<br />

also become less effective in making and implementing policy. Enhanced<br />

bureaucratic transparency, we might speculate, could make such a situation<br />

worse – particularly if such efforts multiply the points <strong>of</strong> access to<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficials and policy processes, and if an increasingly competitive political<br />

process creates more intermediaries seeking to cultivate bureaucratic<br />

friendships. At worst, Influence Markets could turn into a disjointed set<br />

<strong>of</strong> uncoordinated monopolies (Shliefer and Vishny, 1993) – potentially far<br />

more unpredictable and harmful in economic terms than the pre-1993<br />

model (see also Campos, Lien, and Pradhan, 1999; Pascha,1999: 16).<br />

While it is hard to say how likely that outcome is, it would ironically be<br />

partly a consequence <strong>of</strong> the post-1993 reforms.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!