28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

56 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

market democracies too but are perceived as more corrupt, and as a group<br />

have lower (and more scattered) human development rankings. Group 3<br />

(fig. 3.3) is more tightly clustered with the majority (notably, non-African<br />

cases) gathered in a moderately high-corruption/high-development<br />

region. Group 4 (fig. 3.4), while not significantly worse on the TI index<br />

than Group 3, scores lowest in terms <strong>of</strong> human development and – likely<br />

in part because <strong>of</strong> the varying agendas <strong>of</strong> undemocratic leaders – is the<br />

least tightly clustered. That group displays an intriguing division between<br />

a group <strong>of</strong> several Islamic societies with more moderate corruption and<br />

development scores (China is in that region too) and another, tighter<br />

group in the lower right area that includes a number <strong>of</strong> African states.<br />

That contrast too will also be a focus <strong>of</strong> discussion later on.<br />

In a perfect world these clusters would be tighter and more clearly<br />

distinct from each other. But the goal here is not to explain variations in<br />

corruption indices as such; rather it is to suggest that knowing something<br />

about participation and institutions in a country adds to our understanding<br />

<strong>of</strong> corruption – or, at least, sharpens our questions. The qualitative<br />

contrasts not captured by the indices are the major concern <strong>of</strong> this book<br />

and will be brought out in chapters 4–7.<br />

Contrasts in other development indicators also support that view.<br />

(Tables A–C, presenting the data on which the following discussion<br />

is based, appear in appendix B, pp. 225–227). Group 1 countries<br />

(‘‘Influence Markets’’), in aggregate, are stable, well-institutionalized<br />

democracies with free economies; governments are rated as effective and<br />

as intervening in the economy relatively judiciously. Rule <strong>of</strong> law is firmly in<br />

place, leaders face significant political competition and constraints on their<br />

powers, and critics are able to demand accountability effectively. These are<br />

prosperous societies providing a high quality <strong>of</strong> life; they enjoy a favorable<br />

position in world markets, and their experiences thus differ considerably<br />

from those <strong>of</strong> societies more exposed to outside economic interests. While<br />

none <strong>of</strong> these indicators sheds light directly upon corrupt processes,theyare<br />

broadly consistent with the ‘‘Influence Markets’’ scenario: wealth interests<br />

are powerful, but the state is well-institutionalized and corruption does not<br />

seem to undermine the system. That regulatory activities are relatively<br />

narrow in scope and comparatively high-quality suggests that <strong>of</strong>ficials are<br />

less likely to use such powers arbitrarily.<br />

The suggestion here is not that these societies have solved the corruption<br />

problem: the United States in particular has experienced a rash<br />

<strong>of</strong> regulatory failings linked to private-sector fraud. Instead, Group 1<br />

corruption seems relatively contained both within the institutional framework<br />

and in its consequences. The longevity <strong>of</strong> these systems suggests<br />

both that they have developed a working balance between wealth and

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!