28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Elite Cartels 103<br />

Korea: ‘‘money politics’’ and control<br />

Governing Korea has <strong>of</strong>ten been lucrative, but it has never been easy.<br />

With a ‘‘strong state’’ ruling over a ‘‘contentious society’’ (Koo, 1993:<br />

231–249; Clifford, 1994: 11) <strong>of</strong> 48 million citizens on the southern<br />

portion <strong>of</strong> a rocky peninsula, a heritage <strong>of</strong> colonial domination and civil<br />

war, few natural resources, and a national capital just forty miles from the<br />

world’s most tensely guarded border, the Republic <strong>of</strong> Korea has spent the<br />

past half-century in a state <strong>of</strong> crisis (Clifford, 1994: 7; Kang, 2002a: 50).<br />

Its successes therefore are all the more remarkable: from desperate poverty<br />

after the armistice <strong>of</strong> 1953 the country has climbed into the first rank<br />

<strong>of</strong> the world’s economies. Authoritarian government backed by violence<br />

and a tightly integrated national elite kept civil society, political parties,<br />

and electoral politics weak for three decades, yet gave way to democratic<br />

forces in 1987. Out <strong>of</strong> unpromising circumstances Korea has launched an<br />

increasingly competitive and legitimate democracy, so that by now there<br />

seems little threat <strong>of</strong> a relapse into authoritarianism. <strong>Corruption</strong> has been<br />

integral to all <strong>of</strong> these developments, supporting a hegemonic elite, aiding<br />

early economic development, and exacerbating deferred economic risks<br />

and political resentments. It remains a serious concern today.<br />

Korea’s Elite Cartel corruption outwardly resembles the ‘‘money politics’’<br />

seen in Japan (chapter 4). Very large payments by businesses to<br />

political elites – sometimes as ‘‘contributions’’ to parties or foundations,<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten as outright bribes – bought major policy favors. Despite Korea’s<br />

many similarities to Japan, however, I will argue that its money politics<br />

was simpler, more centralized, and helped maintain tightly integrated<br />

state–business–military networks <strong>of</strong> elites. Korean corruption took place<br />

in a setting <strong>of</strong> weaker institutions, and was less a system <strong>of</strong> specific<br />

exchanges between business and political sectors than a continuous<br />

incentive system integral to rule by a political–business–bureaucratic<br />

network (Tat, 1996: 50; Moran, 1999: 582; Steinberg, 2000: 209).<br />

Elite networks included, at various times and in differing kinds <strong>of</strong> balance,<br />

top state <strong>of</strong>ficials (notably, presidents, their families, and their<br />

personal entourages); the heads <strong>of</strong> the chaebols (huge family-controlled<br />

industrial conglomerates); segments <strong>of</strong> the bureaucratic elite; and military<br />

leaders as well. These networks were bound together in part by<br />

corrupt incentives, but also by regional and family loyalties, the threat<br />

from the North, and a continuing need to stave <strong>of</strong>f political and economic<br />

competition. A weak civil society and traditional attitudes toward power<br />

and authority facilitated this style <strong>of</strong> regime; so did its ability, from the<br />

mid-1970s onwards, to deliver economic development and rising living<br />

standards on a breathtaking scale.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!