28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

From analysis to reform 215<br />

Are we there yet?<br />

How do we know whether reform works? The question has no simple<br />

answer. I suggest, however, that we should avoid using opinion-based<br />

corruption indices to track change. How closely such figures correspond<br />

to actual corruption is open to considerable dispute, and the accuracy<br />

with which they reflect change is even more unproven (Johnston, 2001a).<br />

Moreover, such indices are oriented toward bribery, <strong>of</strong>ten at high levels<br />

and involving international trade, and thus tell us less about some kinds <strong>of</strong><br />

corruption than others. Indeed, a country that mounts a serious <strong>of</strong>fensive<br />

against corruption may well find that its perception ratings suffer as legal<br />

proceedings, long-suppressed evidence, and public reaction begin to<br />

make headlines. Surveys <strong>of</strong> the corruption experiences <strong>of</strong> households,<br />

businesses, and <strong>of</strong>ficials are a better strategy in many respects, but they<br />

are expensive and must be repeated frequently. The societies that need<br />

such data most may be least able to afford them.<br />

A more feasible approach is to focus on aspects <strong>of</strong> government that<br />

create incentives to corruption and reflect its effects (Klitgaard et al.,<br />

2000; Johnston, 2005b). A licensing process that takes seven weeks and<br />

involves thirty-two steps is an indirect indicator <strong>of</strong> problems: the delay<br />

itself (<strong>of</strong>ten contrived) creates incentives to pay up while each step is a<br />

potential squeeze point for extortion. A government that pays twice as<br />

much for petrol or concrete as its neighbor or charges suspiciously low<br />

prices for its crude oil is either experiencing or inviting corrupt dealings. If<br />

a tax returns only half the revenue it is projected to yield, or if calculations<br />

and collections involve wide discretion, the same suspicions hold.<br />

Indicators <strong>of</strong> this sort point out areas <strong>of</strong> vulnerability and can help<br />

gauge the effects <strong>of</strong> reforms. If the licensing process is cut back to five<br />

steps and four days, institutions have been improved because reasons to<br />

give and opportunities to get have been curtailed. If prices a government<br />

pays for asphalt fall toward the norm, incentives and opportunities for<br />

kickbacks are being reduced. Routinely gathering and publishing such<br />

indicators is itself an institution-building process. Inviting citizens to rate<br />

the quality <strong>of</strong> services they receive, as in the ‘‘citizen report card’’ system<br />

for the local government <strong>of</strong> Bangalore, India (Wagle and Shah, 2003),<br />

builds popular participation not just in reform but in government generally.<br />

Officials who produce better services can take political credit for<br />

doing so – the real source <strong>of</strong> political will – and synergy between participation<br />

and institutions may begin to build.<br />

A further hint about assessing progress can be found in the basic notion<br />

<strong>of</strong> syndromes <strong>of</strong> corruption. A shift from a more- to a less-disruptive form<br />

<strong>of</strong> corruption – which, as noted, need not necessarily move through all

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!