28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

156 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

private domains are porous or, in effect, non-existent. Indeed, many<br />

Official Moguls operate in a realm between state and society, using<br />

power and resources that are neither clearly public nor private (Johnston<br />

and Hao, 1995). Top-level <strong>of</strong>fices are useful mostly to create monopolies <strong>of</strong><br />

various sorts that are then exploited with few restraints. Some monopolies<br />

may be small-scale affairs while others may allow Official Moguls and their<br />

business clients to dominate major segments <strong>of</strong> an economy.<br />

The results are distinctive kinds <strong>of</strong> connections between wealth and<br />

power. Seeking bureaucratic influence through payments to political<br />

intermediaries, as in our Influence Market cases, is usually pointless.<br />

The <strong>of</strong>ficial policy process <strong>of</strong>ten bears little resemblance to reality, and<br />

those with political power or backing are out for themselves. Top figures in<br />

Official Mogul countries need not form cartel-style networks because<br />

political opposition is weak at best; indeed in many cases there is no<br />

doubt who is in control. Their clients become specialists, exploiting<br />

fragments <strong>of</strong> state authority and opportunities opened up by their<br />

political backers. And unlike Oligarchs who must continually find ways<br />

to reward and discipline their Clans, and to protect their gains, Official<br />

Moguls’ followers have few alternatives and their claims to wealth and<br />

property face little real challenge.<br />

The costs <strong>of</strong> impunity<br />

Official Mogul corruption is driven by the unconstrained abuse <strong>of</strong><br />

political and, by extension, <strong>of</strong>ficial power. There may be one clearly dominant<br />

figure, as in Suharto’s Indonesia, or more numerous Moguls operating<br />

their own monopolies in a more uncoordinated fashion, as in China.<br />

They <strong>of</strong>ten have personal clienteles including relatives, business people,<br />

and local leaders, but there is little political reason to share spoils with<br />

mass constituencies in the manner <strong>of</strong> machine bosses. Economic opportunities<br />

are growing in these societies (see table 7.1), but these cases lack<br />

the political accountability and strong institutions required for an orderly<br />

market economy. Opposing corruption can thus be risky business, and even<br />

those citizens who bitterly resent it may leave the heavy lifting to others.<br />

<strong>Corruption</strong> <strong>of</strong> this type is <strong>of</strong>ten large-scale and free-wheeling, crossing<br />

international borders as well as those between the state and economy.<br />

Indeed, liberalization <strong>of</strong> politics and economies has exacerbated corruption<br />

problems in this group, as we shall see in the cases <strong>of</strong> Kenya and<br />

Indonesia. Like corrupt figures elsewhere, Official Moguls build monopolies<br />

(Klitgaard, 1988): one politician or his client may claim an entire<br />

segment <strong>of</strong> industry while another may simply control the issuance <strong>of</strong> a<br />

valuable permit in a local <strong>of</strong>fice. But these figures have few competitors

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!