28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Oligarchs and Clans 131<br />

The Soviet era: order without markets<br />

It is tempting to think <strong>of</strong> oligarchs, organized crime, and corruption<br />

generally as something new, or as outgrowths <strong>of</strong> post-communist problems<br />

and events. But while the post-1991 climate <strong>of</strong> immense opportunities<br />

and weak institutions has helped make corruption particularly<br />

disruptive, many <strong>of</strong> the underlying problems, and some <strong>of</strong> the key figures<br />

involved, have roots in the old Soviet order. A full discussion <strong>of</strong> Soviet<br />

corruption is beyond the scope <strong>of</strong> this chapter (see Kramer, 1977, 1998;<br />

Schwartz, 1979; Simis, 1982; Vaksberg, 1992), but some points are<br />

essential to what came next. During that era a bureaucratized, centrally<br />

planned economy lacking a price system was ruled by a one-party dictatorship<br />

answerable to no one. Bureaucratic corruption was the norm, not<br />

the exception, as <strong>of</strong>ficials and enterprise managers not only took advantage<br />

<strong>of</strong> illicit opportunities but struggled to keep up the appearance <strong>of</strong><br />

meeting quotas. A parallel system <strong>of</strong> corruption for personal gain<br />

(Kramer, 1977) helped individuals cope with shortages, obtain better<br />

housing, health care, and education, angle for better job assignments,<br />

and generally cushion the impact <strong>of</strong> harsh and arbitrary state policy<br />

(DiFranceisco and Gitelman, 1984; Ledeneva, 1998). At the top <strong>of</strong> the<br />

political structure – and occasionally, at key points in the economy –<br />

corrupt gains could be spectacular (Simis, 1982). <strong>Corruption</strong> was no<br />

secret during those days, but <strong>of</strong>ficial acknowledgment <strong>of</strong> the problem<br />

was sporadic and usually served political ends. When a top <strong>of</strong>ficial was<br />

publicly labeled corrupt, that <strong>of</strong>ten meant that he or she had come out on<br />

the losing side <strong>of</strong> a factional struggle.<br />

Bureaucratic corruption helped the system survive in a distorted and<br />

inefficient form by easing bottlenecks and creating a crude sort <strong>of</strong><br />

exchange system. By the last decades <strong>of</strong> the Soviet era it was far less<br />

risky for the regime to wink at corruption than to undertake fundamental<br />

reform. <strong>Corruption</strong> was hardly beneficial, but alternatives were few and<br />

had huge potential costs. Long-term damage came in the form <strong>of</strong> lost<br />

opportunities to change and adapt, and in a pervasive cynicism about<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficial statements and policies. The result was a system that in the end<br />

could not bend, but rather broke.<br />

For our purposes four aspects <strong>of</strong> the Soviet era are <strong>of</strong> particular importance.<br />

First, the party-state apparatus was large and monopolistic, but in<br />

many ways ineffective. The state bureaucracy was slow-moving and<br />

deeply politicized; the party ruthlessly punished opponents and <strong>of</strong>fered<br />

no legitimate way to influence policy from below. Even had it been spared<br />

the worst <strong>of</strong> the dislocations and dubious policy advice (Stiglitz, 2002)<br />

that accompanied the fall <strong>of</strong> the Soviet order, a state that had ruled by

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!