28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

70 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

Mo st incumbe nts se eking re-elect ion win easily. Betw een 1980 and<br />

2004, the sha re <strong>of</strong> Hou se incumbe nts seeking re-ele ction and winning<br />

ran ged between 90.5 an d 98.8 percent, and the share winning with at<br />

leas t 60 percent <strong>of</strong> the vot e ranged bet ween 65.2 and 88.0 perce nt.<br />

In 2004, on ly five incumbent s were def eated (redis tricting forced two<br />

othe r inc umbents to run agai nst eac h ot her). Nearly a quarte r <strong>of</strong> Hou s<br />

incumbe nts, in most yea rs, face token opposit ion or none at all. In<br />

the Senate , re-election rates are only somewha t lower: in 1980, the year<br />

<strong>of</strong> a Republic an landslide large enou gh to ou st an incumbe nt Presid ent,<br />

64.0 perce nt <strong>of</strong> Senators runn ing f or re-elect ion won, 40 perce nt ta king<br />

six votes out <strong>of</strong> te n, or more. Between 1982 and 2004 the perce ntage<br />

<strong>of</strong> incumbent s winni ng their re-election campa igns ranged bet ween<br />

75.0 and 96.9. In 2004, 25 <strong>of</strong> 26 Senators se eking re-e lection were<br />

victorious, and 69.2 percent <strong>of</strong> them topped 60 percent <strong>of</strong> the vote<br />

(Common Cause, 2002; Ornstein, Mann, and Malbin, 2002; Campaign<br />

Finance Institute, 2004).<br />

Incumbent advantage is less decisive in presidential races, which<br />

attract politically established challengers and major donors, and where<br />

incumbents are limited to two terms. Here the law does not so much<br />

enshrine incumbents as prop up the present party system. New parties<br />

and independent candidates face a high threshold (5 percent <strong>of</strong> the<br />

popular vote) to qualify for even a fraction <strong>of</strong> the public funding given<br />

to candidates <strong>of</strong> the two established parties, and <strong>of</strong> course can only claim<br />

such funds after the election. Had today’s rules been in place in 1860,<br />

Abraham Lincoln might well have run as a Whig.<br />

Incumbent success may reflect effectiveness at working for a state or<br />

district, good constituent service, and the accumulated name recognition<br />

that flows from incumbency itself. But if challengers so rarely win<br />

and are unlikely to attract contributions that will discourage all but<br />

the wealthiest would-be legislators from mounting a serious run.<br />

Campaigns <strong>of</strong>fering a wide range <strong>of</strong> viewpoints <strong>of</strong>fered by viable candidates<br />

have become the exception. The role <strong>of</strong> contributors is also<br />

affected: incumbents know they can win with or without a given contributor,<br />

can outspend most challengers with ease, and therefore owe<br />

that contributor nothing. Seasoned lobbyists and individual contributors<br />

virtually never make quid pro quo <strong>of</strong>fers, and scorn anyone who<br />

would. Indeed, one study concluded that incumbents’ security is so<br />

extensive, and donors’ leverage is so slight, that contributions more<br />

closely resemble protection payments than legalized bribes (Keim and<br />

Zardkoohi, 1988). Many donors are critical <strong>of</strong> the current system and<br />

the relationships it creates (Green, 1998) – not a result one would<br />

expect if donations simply bought favorable policy. The real corruption

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!