28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Elite Cartels 111<br />

their power; afterwards electoral competition gradually increased.<br />

In either phase building a power base while staying within the rules was<br />

a doubtful proposition: parties were weak and personalized, society was<br />

poorly organized and fractious, and political elites were guided more by<br />

personal, regional, and family loyalties than by <strong>of</strong>ficial duties or<br />

policy commitments. Elite Cartel corruption solidified power but<br />

reinforced those systemic problems. It likely helped Korea maintain<br />

order through the difficulties <strong>of</strong> political transition, and provided<br />

elites with predictability in the early years <strong>of</strong> the new regime.<br />

Business–political–bureaucratic networks evolved over time (Kim<br />

Joongi, 2002: 174ff.): as the chaebols grew their power within the elite<br />

stratum increased, but they never became dominant over the top political<br />

figures (Kang, 2002a). Sharing political money with opposition leaders<br />

was a way to pacify them in the short term and to accumulate damning<br />

evidence for use later on. But building broad-based, competitive electoral<br />

politics proved a slow process, and both credible anti-corruption reform<br />

(as opposed to spectacular trials <strong>of</strong> past presidents) and creating a strong<br />

civil society remain challenges a generation after the transition.<br />

Much as Elite Cartel corruption enabled Italy to realize impressive<br />

growth despite a blocked political system and only moderately effective<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficial institutions, Korea’s particular style <strong>of</strong> corruption likely aided<br />

the economic take<strong>of</strong>f and underwrote a measure <strong>of</strong> political continuity<br />

through the democratic transition and the aftermath <strong>of</strong> the 1997–8<br />

economic crisis. This does not mean that corruption is inherently<br />

beneficial: particularly in the long run, as chapter 2 shows, the evidence<br />

runs strongly to the contrary. Moderate economic policy changes, and<br />

measures for political and corporate accountability, that might<br />

havestaved<strong>of</strong>ftheworst<strong>of</strong>theeconomicmeltdownwerenotimplemented<br />

in Korea. The logic <strong>of</strong> Elite Cartels – rather than aggregate<br />

amounts <strong>of</strong> corruption – preempted economic and political<br />

adaptation, turning the need for a variety <strong>of</strong> small changes into an<br />

eventual systemic crisis.<br />

Cheng and Chu’s notion (2002: 57) <strong>of</strong> a state that, in Korea’s authoritarian<br />

phase, was ‘‘neither predatory nor captured,’’ raises one final issue:<br />

because <strong>of</strong> its internal logic Korean corruption might have been selflimiting<br />

in important respects (see also Kang, 2002a). Both accounts<br />

suggest that those who are strong enough to form cartels are also in a<br />

position to check excesses that might undermine their advantages. But<br />

the question is complex: if by limits to corruption it is meant that overall<br />

amounts were restricted we would need somehow to guess how much<br />

corruption would otherwise have occurred – an exercise that is conjectural<br />

at best. But limits could also refer to the scope <strong>of</strong> corruption – who

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!