28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

218 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

down by members <strong>of</strong> the aristocracy weary <strong>of</strong> royal abuses. Critical<br />

notions <strong>of</strong> accountable government in England emerged out <strong>of</strong> a blood<br />

feud between crown and parliament over taxation, religion, and the<br />

accountability <strong>of</strong> royal ministers (Roberts, 1966: 91; Johnston, 1993) –<br />

not as reforms but as clubs to swing in a political brawl. Similarly, election<br />

reform in nineteenth-century Britain – the secret ballot, limits on expenditures,<br />

and the long struggle over rotten boroughs – was in part aimed at<br />

checking the ‘‘old corruption,’’ but also helped party leaders impose order<br />

on, and control the costs <strong>of</strong>, the growing nationwide competition for votes<br />

(O’Leary, 1962; Finer, 1975; Rubinstein, 1983; Cox, 1986). Botswana<br />

by most measures ought to have more corruption, in more disruptive<br />

forms, than it seems to experience. Its working political framework was<br />

no one’s design for reform or good government, but rather an elite<br />

settlement, rooted in society itself, that reconciled important groups<br />

and values and provided a coherent basis for effective rule. In Korea it<br />

is more difficult to say whether the glass is half full or half empty in<br />

corruption terms, but there is little doubt that the country is better <strong>of</strong>f<br />

than it was thirty years ago. Its transitions followed no overall plan but<br />

rather were arrangements in which important leaders and factions <strong>of</strong> a<br />

contentious society had their stakes.<br />

Ultimately corruption and reform are questions <strong>of</strong> justice. Can government<br />

protect the rights and opportunities <strong>of</strong> the many against the interests<br />

<strong>of</strong> a few, and can it be held accountable? Are boundaries between<br />

public and private power sufficient to prevent either from overrunning the<br />

other? A generation <strong>of</strong> liberalization sought to protect private interests<br />

from an encroaching state, but in many places has weakened key public<br />

institutions and political constraints, inviting abuses <strong>of</strong> private power.<br />

Too <strong>of</strong>ten we have pretended that giving free rein to private interests will<br />

quickly create self-regulating substitutes for government. But who then<br />

protects the weak? Shifting that burden to civil society, perversely, can be<br />

a way <strong>of</strong> blaming the victims.<br />

For that reason reform must ultimately involve deep democratization.<br />

By that I mean not just competitive elections or transparency schemes,<br />

valuable as they are, but rather enabling citizens to pursue and defend<br />

their values and interests freely, and to settle upon acceptable institutions<br />

and ways <strong>of</strong> using wealth and power. Citizens, <strong>of</strong> course, are not automatically<br />

endowed with collective wisdom. They must want to build and<br />

sustain those settlements, and to endure the effort and risk that are<br />

involved. But they are more likely to do so in defense <strong>of</strong> their own wellbeing<br />

than in the name <strong>of</strong> ‘‘being good.’’ It is incumbent upon anyone<br />

concerned with government, development, and democracy to make sure<br />

such opportunities are accessible, credible, and safe. There is a wide gap

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!