28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

48 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

degrees, along with a number <strong>of</strong> African countries (particularly those<br />

marked by military rule and internal strife). China’s economic reforms<br />

and spectacular growth are well known, but as we shall see in chapter 7<br />

they have been accompanied by extensive corruption, <strong>of</strong>ten driven by<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficials exploiting segments <strong>of</strong> an increasingly fragmented party and state<br />

apparatus. In Kenya and Indonesia powerful elites have engaged in<br />

rapacious corruption that has been exacerbated, if anything, by the<br />

launching <strong>of</strong> competitive elections without the supporting institutions<br />

they require. Other countries in which strong elites have pursued reforms<br />

may be about to escape a high-corruption/low-development trap<br />

(Johnston, 1998): Uganda is no democracy as yet, but it has implemented<br />

important anti-corruption measures and increased opportunities for popular<br />

participation (Ruzindana, 1997). Even during periods <strong>of</strong> reform,<br />

however, the state (or fragments <strong>of</strong> it) may remain handy for exploitation<br />

by rulers accountable to no one.<br />

These four corruption syndromes remain ideal types at this point,<br />

meant to describe (and highlight contrasts among) corruption problems<br />

I suggest we will find when participation and institutional factors combine<br />

in certain commonly observed ways. No country will have just one<br />

kind <strong>of</strong> corruption, and no syndrome will fit any one case in every detail.<br />

All are grounded in the notion that political and economic liberalization<br />

has placed stresses upon institutional frameworks, which themselves vary<br />

considerably in strength.<br />

A few overall contrasts are worth noting too. As we move from Influence<br />

Markets toward Official Moguls we shift from corruption structured along<br />

lines <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial roles and processes to that which is scarcely institutionalized<br />

at all. The former seeks to convert wealth into bureaucratic influence or<br />

electoral success, while the latter is the open exploitation <strong>of</strong> power, and <strong>of</strong><br />

the weak by the strong. Influence Market and Elite Cartel corruption<br />

involve repeated transactions and influence or access usable over a long<br />

term; indeed, Elite Cartel corruption may be used primarily to forestall or<br />

at least control change. In Oligarch and Clan and Official Mogul cases,<br />

however, corruption is less predictable, <strong>of</strong>ten involving targets <strong>of</strong> opportunity<br />

in rapidly changing societies or the whims <strong>of</strong> leaders acting with<br />

impunity. Where institutions are stronger opponents <strong>of</strong> corruption can<br />

organize, relying upon relatively sound civil liberties, legal frameworks,<br />

and civil societies; where they are weak anti-corruption activity becomes<br />

increasingly risky. Finally, in the latter sorts <strong>of</strong> cases corruption may be not<br />

the exception but the norm, at least in certain segments <strong>of</strong> politics and the<br />

economy. More than any other, that contrast suggests the contrasting<br />

expectations, relationships between wealth and power, and reform challenges<br />

to be found among the world’s cases <strong>of</strong> corruption.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!