28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

76 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

oil giant Elf-Aquitaine to take over an aging refinery at Leuna, in the old<br />

East, and market its products. Payments to Kohl skimmed from such<br />

dealings amounted to DM2 million or more; his refusal to disclose their<br />

sources led (after Kohl’s election loss in 1999) to his resignation as CDU<br />

honorary chairman, and to major investigations. All three major parties<br />

received payments; one account put the total at DM100 million while one<br />

‘‘bagman’’ claimed that DM85 million went to one party alone.<br />

Take the money and run<br />

These sorts <strong>of</strong> dealings are aided by relatively weak legal and political<br />

constraints. Germany did introduce new controls on party contributions<br />

in the 1980s, but there are no limits and no bar against contributions by<br />

corporations or in cash (Alemann, 2002). Bribery <strong>of</strong> Bundestag members is<br />

a legal <strong>of</strong>fense, but the law is not vigorously enforced. Bribery <strong>of</strong> or through<br />

parties is illegal, with parties obliged to repay illegally received funds plus<br />

penalties to the Presidium <strong>of</strong> the Bundestag, which will then turn such<br />

sums over to charity (Alemann, 2002). Most <strong>of</strong> the burden for monitoring<br />

such contributions, however, falls upon the parties themselves (Germany’s<br />

anti-corruption laws and their enforcement are analyzed in GRECO,<br />

2004). Finally, as the cases above suggest, top figures <strong>of</strong>ten enjoy de facto<br />

immunity (Seibel, 1997: 89, 94–96): jail terms are rare, criminal charges<br />

are likely to deal with tax evasion rather than bribery, and political careers<br />

may continue with little loss <strong>of</strong> standing. Edmund Stoiber, CSU Interior<br />

Minister in Bavaria, who admitted in the early 1990s to receiving personal<br />

favors from businesses, went on to become Prime Minister <strong>of</strong> Bavaria and,<br />

by 2002, CDU/CSU leader and candidate for Chancellor. The dynamics<br />

<strong>of</strong> German democratization noted above may have devalued democratic<br />

accountability while emphasizing the mere distribution <strong>of</strong> social benefits<br />

(Seibel, 1997: 96–99); in any event, the resentment <strong>of</strong> Influence Markets<br />

evident among American citizens is not apparent in Germany.<br />

Germany thus shows how Influence Markets adapt to political realities.<br />

A US Senator or Representative has more policy leverage than an individual<br />

Bundestag member, but in the German system major influence can<br />

be had at higher levels – <strong>of</strong>ten, among the leaders <strong>of</strong> more than one party.<br />

Those leaders and their parties have a common interest in a political and<br />

electoral system in which they <strong>of</strong>ten share power, and in continuing to<br />

distribute material benefits. Germany’s economy, too, is distinguished by<br />

the presence <strong>of</strong> very large private corporations, labor unions, and other<br />

groups with major funds at their disposal. The result is an Influence<br />

Market that flourishes at high levels, crosses party lines, and involves<br />

relatively few risks.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!