28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

166 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

egregious <strong>of</strong>fenses – economic, political, or both. Such abuses might well<br />

attract extreme penalties in any event but the party-state, having relatively<br />

few opportunities to win credibility for anti-corruption decrees, <strong>of</strong>ten seeks<br />

the maximum demonstration effects possible.<br />

The party: leaders in search <strong>of</strong> a following<br />

It was the Communist Party that founded the People’s Republic and<br />

provided such discipline and coherence as it possessed for its first thirty<br />

years. Ideological direction, political education, and thought-reform<br />

extended downward into work groups and neighborhoods. Since at<br />

least the 1980s, however, the party has been beset by organizational rot.<br />

Lü Xiaobo characterizes that process as ‘‘involution’’: the failure <strong>of</strong> the<br />

party either to transform itself into a rationalized administrative regime or<br />

to sustain its revolutionary strengths. Caught in that contradiction, cadres<br />

fall back upon traditional practices and norms (Lü, 2000: 22) or just go<br />

through the motions. Older and more personal modes <strong>of</strong> getting things<br />

done – notably kinship and the web <strong>of</strong> ties and reciprocities known as<br />

guanxi – resurface, at times in updated forms (Kipnis, 1997; Gold,<br />

Gut hrie, and Wa nk, 2002 ; Ku, 2003 ; Peng, 2004) . Party le aders have<br />

r esponded w ith per io dic d iscipline camp aig ns, but they failed to r e-ener giz<br />

cadre commitm ents or local organizati on. A recent self-e valuation concluded<br />

that half <strong>of</strong> the party’s rural cells were ‘‘weak’’ or ‘‘paralyzed’’;<br />

meanwhile, the party presence within new business organizations is nearly<br />

non-existent (Pei, 2002). Part <strong>of</strong> the problem is that the party attempts to<br />

perform irreconcilable roles: Gong argues that ideological purity conflicts<br />

with the practicalities <strong>of</strong> governing, particularly during an era <strong>of</strong> reform<br />

and rapid change; the party’s need for discipline inhibits the development<br />

<strong>of</strong> an autonomous and effective bureaucracy; and political goals conflict<br />

with effective policy implementation. In the end party and state elites<br />

‘‘become an elite group in itself and for itself’’ (Gong, 1994: xviii-xix, and<br />

ch. 8) – a good working definition <strong>of</strong> Official Mogul corruption.<br />

<strong>Corruption</strong> is just one <strong>of</strong> China’s problems, but it is a particularly<br />

critical one – not just because <strong>of</strong> its scope, which no one knows with<br />

any precision, but because it takes a particularly damaging form. Official<br />

Mogul corruption is symptomatic <strong>of</strong> deeper problems that raise real<br />

doubts about whether China, over the middle to long term, can be<br />

governed at all. Pei (2002) suggests China may be approaching a governability<br />

crisis in which the administrative shortcomings <strong>of</strong> a ‘‘feeble state’’<br />

are compounded by a deteriorating party unable to deal with the changes<br />

it has unleashed. The party-state’s response, so far, has been to avoid<br />

political liberalization. Over the short term that strategy maintains party

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!