28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

72 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

spare time in the company <strong>of</strong> wealthy people and their particular view <strong>of</strong><br />

the world, and corresponding expectations among the wealthy that they<br />

have special claims, likewise do little for the quality <strong>of</strong> representative<br />

democracy.<br />

The corruption problem: not bribery but bad politics<br />

The United States has a systemic corruption problem involving political<br />

finance, but not necessarily the one much <strong>of</strong> the public thinks it has.<br />

Bribery <strong>of</strong> federal elected <strong>of</strong>ficials is uncommon, and there is little evidence<br />

that large donors can buy Congressional votes. More bribery and extortion<br />

occur at lower levels, but again its scope is relatively limited: the US fills<br />

over half a million public <strong>of</strong>fices by elections, all but 537 <strong>of</strong> them through<br />

state and local elections. At issue, instead, are the vitality and credibility <strong>of</strong><br />

electoral politics. Popular majorities believe the campaign finance process is<br />

corrupting, and there is a significant gap among laws, social values, and the<br />

elite political culture regarding acceptable behavior. Further, campaign<br />

finance laws protect incumbents, thereby (in conjunction with other<br />

developments) reducing political competition and the apparent value <strong>of</strong><br />

voting as a mechanism <strong>of</strong> accountability. The institutions regulating the<br />

connections between wealth and power in the American electoral process<br />

have serious credibility problems, and voter participation takes place in<br />

a setting <strong>of</strong> little real competition for many <strong>of</strong>fices. Those add up to a<br />

systemic corruption problem in the sense spelled out in chapter 1.<br />

The new BCRA will likely add to incumbents’ advantages. Whatever its<br />

other drawbacks ‘‘s<strong>of</strong>t money’’ could be used by party leadership to help<br />

challengers via get-out-the-vote activities and party advertising. The new<br />

law restricts fundraising and spending to hard money only, an arena in<br />

which incumbents fare far better than challengers. Similarly, ‘‘issue<br />

advertising’’ – in the past, used more by national groups seeking change<br />

than by backers <strong>of</strong> incumbents – may now be funded by hard money only,<br />

and is therefore banned for advocacy groups, in the final phases <strong>of</strong><br />

campaigns. Perhaps the most incumbent-friendly part <strong>of</strong> BCRA is its<br />

‘‘Millionaire Opponent’’ provision. For House and Senate candidates<br />

limits on individual contributions are raised, and ceilings on party spending<br />

on their behalf are removed, as opponents’ expenditures from personal<br />

funds exceed a series <strong>of</strong> thresholds. While the law applies to all candidates,<br />

self-financing is much more essential to challengers than incumbents: in<br />

most years House challengers (many <strong>of</strong> them political newcomers) raise<br />

between 15 and 25 percent <strong>of</strong> their campaign money from their own funds<br />

(Ornstein, Mann, and Malbin, 2002). Even if they spent vast sums <strong>of</strong> their<br />

own to win the first time, incumbents can easily fund re-election campaigns

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!