28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

The international setting 19<br />

or uneven economic liberalization. The state and politics are, <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

as not, seen as parts <strong>of</strong> the problem, rather than as essential elements<br />

<strong>of</strong> development and reform (Weingast, 1993; Schneider, 1998).<br />

Governing is reduced to public management functions while complex<br />

questions <strong>of</strong> democracy and justice are to be addressed through<br />

technically sound ‘‘good governance’’ rather than politics. There is little<br />

attempt to differentiate among corruption problems, either between<br />

or within societies; instead, much research seeks to explain variations<br />

in whole countries’ scores on one-dimensional corruption indices.<br />

There are thus few variations in suggested reforms, and little<br />

guidance as to which remedies should be applied first, later, or not<br />

at all.<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> these limitations could be seen in anti-corruption strategy<br />

statements issued in the late 1990s by major international<br />

organizations. The United States Agency for International<br />

Development, in its 1998 USAID Handbook for Fighting <strong>Corruption</strong>,<br />

presented good case studies <strong>of</strong> Hong Kong, Mexico, and Tanzania<br />

(USAID, 1998: 21–39), and <strong>of</strong>fered a useful overview <strong>of</strong> anti-corruption<br />

measures (ibid.: 8–15). But while the document acknowledged the<br />

need for flexible responses and discussed social as well as institutional<br />

causes, there was little systematic comparison <strong>of</strong> cases. The World<br />

Bank strategy document ‘‘Helping Countries Combat <strong>Corruption</strong>’’<br />

<strong>of</strong>fered a range <strong>of</strong> good-governance measures and advocated continued<br />

economic liberalization, but treated anti-corruption reform in very<br />

general terms and did not differentiate among types <strong>of</strong> cases (World<br />

Bank, 1997: chs. 2–6). The UNDP discussion paper ‘‘<strong>Corruption</strong> and<br />

Good Governance’’ proposed attacking the ‘‘micro’’ logic <strong>of</strong> bribery<br />

(UNDP, 1997: 52–59) but did not extend the analysis to other<br />

varieties <strong>of</strong> corruption; proposed reforms again dealt mostly with<br />

improved law enforcement and public management (ibid.: ch. 3).<br />

The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development<br />

(OECD), in <strong>Corruption</strong> and Integrity Improvement Initiatives in<br />

Developing Countries (1998), discussed some conceptual issues but<br />

did not distinguish systematically among types <strong>of</strong> cases. Emphasis<br />

was on political will at top levels, law enforcement, institutional<br />

reform and technical skills, mobilizing civil society, and economic liberalization<br />

(OECD, 1998). The Year 2000 Sourcebook <strong>of</strong> Transparency<br />

International (TI) acknowledged four types <strong>of</strong> bribery (Transparency<br />

International, 2000: 16–17), but beyond a mention <strong>of</strong> extortion did<br />

not explore other sorts <strong>of</strong> corruption. Indeed, at one point it asserts<br />

that ‘‘corruption in China ... is really no different from that in<br />

Europe’’ (ibid.: 15–16).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!