28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

128 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

simply lent the government’s own deposits back to it), and the ‘‘auctions’’<br />

that followed were rigged. Foreign bidders were barred while oligarchs<br />

colluded on their bids, dividing major assets among themselves at extremely<br />

low prices. The loans were made before the 1996 presidential<br />

election, in which Boris Yeltsin faced significant challenges, while the<br />

resolution <strong>of</strong> the scheme took place after. The loans enabled Yeltsin to<br />

make good on public obligations, pay some back salaries, and finance his<br />

campaign at a level one hundred times higher than the legal limit. The<br />

oligarchs, meanwhile, acquired an interest in Yeltsin’s re-election so that<br />

the scheme could be seen through to conclusion (Freeland, 2000:<br />

169–189, 194–195; Reddaway and Glinski, 2001; Shelley, 2001: 246;<br />

Hudson, 2004).<br />

Another more specific scheme involved Russia’s aluminum industry.<br />

In the mid-1990s a syndicate led by Oleg Deripaska and ‘‘Yeltsin family’’<br />

backers used corrupt influence, rigged bids, and the threat <strong>of</strong> violence to<br />

take over the industry at knock-down prices. Entrepreneurs in other<br />

industries, not all related to metals production, have complained more<br />

recently <strong>of</strong> legal and illegal pressures, and outright threats <strong>of</strong> violence,<br />

from those same forces seeking to expand the aluminum empire.<br />

Aluminum production requires large amounts <strong>of</strong> electricity: one reason<br />

why Deripaska’s clan acquired major influence in the energy sector as<br />

well (Ivanidze, 2002; Tavernise, 2002a; Reut and Rubnikovich, 2003).<br />

Evidence <strong>of</strong> corruption was a saleable commodity in the Soviet era, but<br />

now the market is booming. Kompromat – a contraction <strong>of</strong> ‘‘compromising<br />

materials’’ – involves the use <strong>of</strong> evidence <strong>of</strong> corruption to threaten<br />

political and economic rivals as well as uncooperative <strong>of</strong>ficials.<br />

Journalists, investigators, and politicians amass incriminating information<br />

(easily obtainable, but forged if need be) and sell it back to the person<br />

involved; if the target will not pay, the evidence can just as well be sold to a<br />

newspaper. The effectiveness <strong>of</strong> kompromat reflects the abundance <strong>of</strong><br />

corruption itself, the ineffectiveness <strong>of</strong> state investigators and law enforcement,<br />

and a climate <strong>of</strong> lawlessness that makes even fictitious allegations<br />

widely believed (Karklins, 2002: 28–32; Szilágyi, 2002).<br />

The Putin government has made tax reform a priority, in part for<br />

revenue reasons but also as a way to demonstrate a measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial<br />

credibility. Tax evasion, in itself, is not necessarily corruption, but in<br />

Russia it reflects oligarchs’ power and the state’s ineffectiveness.<br />

Simplifications <strong>of</strong> the tax code enacted in 1999 have increased revenues<br />

to some extent and, by limiting discretion in the calculation <strong>of</strong> taxes owed,<br />

may have reduced some low-level corruption. But some oligarchs and<br />

bankers continue to enjoy near-impunity regarding taxes, while the state<br />

scrambles for revenue and many public servants are paid poorly or not at

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!