28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

214 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

unscrupulous leaders and their protégés opens up an intriguing possibility<br />

not available in Elite Cartel or Oligarch and Clan societies. Could<br />

new leaders with an anti-corruption agenda use their unchecked power,<br />

along with a sharp tightening <strong>of</strong> law enforcement and monitoring <strong>of</strong><br />

business excesses, to ‘‘flip’’ an Official Mogul society into a new, lowcorruption<br />

situation? Imagine such a leadership refusing to get involved<br />

in corruption, cracking down on former protégés, and using its power<br />

and resources to support legitimate economic alternatives. Such efforts<br />

could make Moguls more secure by reducing international pressure for<br />

change, and through the social benefits <strong>of</strong> additional economic growth and<br />

reduced political exploitation. They could even make power more pr<strong>of</strong>itable<br />

to the extent that the pool <strong>of</strong> perquisites, while smaller after reform,<br />

would not have to be shared with clients. Such incentives make this<br />

scenario less fanciful than it might seem.<br />

In the longer term that regime would need to embark on more conventional<br />

forms, increasing the pay <strong>of</strong> honest <strong>of</strong>ficials, judges, customs<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficers, and police (perhaps using repatriated proceeds <strong>of</strong> past corruption?),<br />

enhance transparency and guarantee that citizens and journalists<br />

could take advantage <strong>of</strong> it without fear, and strengthen the institutions<br />

protecting economic opportunities and gains. It would also have to deal<br />

with the grievances <strong>of</strong> would-be clients now cut out <strong>of</strong> their expected<br />

rewards and the resentments by citizens and emergent civil society<br />

groups <strong>of</strong> mistreatment under the old regime. Still, some such changes –<br />

notably, higher pay for honest service, and a crackdown on corruption<br />

as part <strong>of</strong> a dash to growth – were implemented in Singapore in a<br />

relatively short time (Quah, 2003), with dramatic results. Rapid, guided<br />

change <strong>of</strong> this order will be more difficult in large-scale societies;<br />

further, getting such leaders to yield eventually to open and competitive<br />

politics is something that despite its successes Singapore has yet to do.<br />

But few gave Korean democratization much <strong>of</strong> a chance at the time<br />

Ferdinand Marcos was ousted in the Philippines in 1986, and yet within<br />

two years a breakthrough had occurred. Admittedly, the elements <strong>of</strong> this<br />

scenario range from the possible to the fanciful to the pathologically<br />

optimistic. But the point is that if we see countries as moving toward a<br />

reform ideal from several different directions rather than along a single<br />

path, many different processes <strong>of</strong> change can be seen.<br />

Processes <strong>of</strong> change: ends and means<br />

Two questions remain. How can we assess the effects <strong>of</strong> anti-corruption<br />

strategies? How can citizens be brought into the process, lest reforms<br />

simply create a few new winners and millions <strong>of</strong> losers?

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!