28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Participation, institutions, and syndromes <strong>of</strong> corruption 57<br />

power and that, unlike developing countries today, they had a long time<br />

to institutionalize and adapt those sorts <strong>of</strong> agreements – a point to which I<br />

will return in discussing reform.<br />

In Group 2 (‘‘Elite Cartels’’) there are more uncertainties and fewer<br />

restraints upon political and economic elites. Political systems and markets<br />

are relatively open and stable (though less so than in Group 1), and<br />

these societies are moderately affluent. But elites face significant competition<br />

in a setting where institutions are more problematic: political rights,<br />

civil liberties, and the rule <strong>of</strong> law are less secure, government and corruption<br />

controls less effective, regulation somewhat more extensive and <strong>of</strong><br />

lower quality, and black markets more pervasive than in Group 1. The<br />

relatively constrained political leaders in this increasingly competitive but<br />

less stable institutional environment might find alliances with business,<br />

media, military, and other elites particularly useful. For some countries in<br />

this group this state <strong>of</strong> affairs is the result <strong>of</strong> successful democratic and<br />

market transitions (Chile, Hungary, Poland, South Africa, South Korea),<br />

but others (Argentina, Belgium, Italy) have experienced crises or deterioration<br />

in existing institutions and political settlements. Those countries<br />

might present comparable statistical pr<strong>of</strong>iles at a given time, but be<br />

changing in different ways – an issue for the case studies to come.<br />

Group 3 countries (‘‘Oligarchs and Clans’’) present an even more<br />

complex, and in many ways pessimistic, picture. Political and economic<br />

liberalization have come a long way but underlying institutions are<br />

problems. Political competition is extensive but political rights, accountability,<br />

civil liberties, and the rule <strong>of</strong> law are markedly less secure than in<br />

our first two groups. Both political and economic actors will find it<br />

difficult to protect their positions in such systems, and potential anticorruption<br />

forces are weak. Leaders face fewer political constraints and<br />

regimes are less stable. Government is ineffective, regulation extensive<br />

and <strong>of</strong> dubious quality, and corruption controls are weak. Economic<br />

opportunities are growing but relatively few seem to benefit (Gini scores<br />

in table B, appendix B, p. 226, suggest high levels <strong>of</strong> inequality), and<br />

black markets are extensive. Further problems grow out <strong>of</strong> the disadvantageous<br />

place these countries occupy in the world economy. They are, on<br />

the whole, poor societies in need <strong>of</strong> international capital, but foreign<br />

domestic investment is weak and there is moderate to heavy reliance<br />

upon primary exports (ores, minerals, food, and the like). Officials must<br />

deal with international economic interests who, facing weak institutions<br />

and unstable regimes, are likely to seek short-term returns rather than<br />

longer-term engagement (Keefer, 1996) and to circumvent taxation and<br />

regulation in any way they can. Local entrepreneurs’ positions are no more<br />

secure, and they too may amass as much wealth as they can, as quickly as

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!