28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

182 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

forms <strong>of</strong> patronage, and helped maintain the personal rule <strong>of</strong> the<br />

President. But it also fed upon, and embodied, a system <strong>of</strong> control that<br />

ended in 1998, and changes since that time may be driving the country in<br />

an Oligarch and Clan direction. President Megawati Soekarnoputri<br />

attempted to rebuild a portion <strong>of</strong> the old national political machine, but<br />

still lost the 2004 presidential run<strong>of</strong>f to former General Susilo Bambang<br />

Yudhoyono by a 60 to 37 percent margin. Yudhoyono is able, educated,<br />

and unlike Megawati is actively interested in governing (New York Times,<br />

September 22, 2004). But the fragmentation <strong>of</strong> politicized state monopolies,<br />

frantic competition among dozens <strong>of</strong> parties desperate for cash,<br />

chronic violence, weak and corrupt courts and judiciary, and the major<br />

natural resources and economic opportunities at stake in Indonesia might<br />

well remind us <strong>of</strong> early-1990s Russia. Any such claim is <strong>of</strong> course<br />

speculative at best, and will require careful continuing study: some<br />

New Order figures, political habits, patterns <strong>of</strong> bureaucratic corruption,<br />

and military influence remain potent (Cole, 2001: 16–17; Malley, 2003:<br />

143–145).<br />

Conclusion: hopeless cases?<br />

We have come quite some distance from the Influence Market cases that<br />

have done so much to shape international thinking about corruption and<br />

reform. From situations in which private interests seek relatively specific<br />

influence within strong institutions we have arrived at a syndrome in<br />

which powerful state and political <strong>of</strong>ficials plunder the economy and<br />

society more or less as they please. This sort <strong>of</strong> corruption – like the<br />

Oligarchs and Clans syndrome – has devastating implications for democratic<br />

development. Its economic implications are more complex; indeed,<br />

some societies in the Official Moguls group have experienced long<br />

periods <strong>of</strong> sustained growth while corruption flourished, and in<br />

Indonesia and some <strong>of</strong> its neighbors growth was part <strong>of</strong> a national<br />

political settlement that helped corrupt <strong>of</strong>ficials stay on top. Perhaps<br />

these countries would have grown even faster with less corruption, but<br />

that is difficult to know. Moguls such as Suharto, development-minded<br />

and willing to use corrupt influence to create commitment mechanisms<br />

for the state and major entrepreneurs, are corrupt monopolists, but their<br />

regimes operate more like coordinated monopolies than the much more<br />

destructive uncoordinated kind (Shleifer and Vishny, 1993; MacIntyre,<br />

2003). Still, such economies would seem less open and adaptive than successful<br />

markets – a possible contributor to the Asian crisis <strong>of</strong> the late 1990s.<br />

Those sorts <strong>of</strong> ideas must await further exploration elsewhere. What is<br />

clear though is that simply to say China, Kenya, and Indonesia rank

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!