28.02.2015 Views

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

CORRUPTION Syndromes of Corruption

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

122 <strong>Syndromes</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Corruption</strong><br />

weakness <strong>of</strong> formal institutions. But Oligarch and Clan corruption feeds<br />

upon and reinforces pervasive insecurity, and unpredictable corruption is<br />

the most damaging <strong>of</strong> all in development terms (Johnson, Kaufmann, and<br />

Zoido-Lobatón,1998; Campos, Lien, and Pradhan, 1999). Investors are<br />

likely to insist on short-term gains rather than planning for the long haul –<br />

or will stay out <strong>of</strong> a country altogether (Keefer, 1996). Safer institutions<br />

and more sustainable returns abroad encourage capital flight. A lack <strong>of</strong><br />

orderly development does not, however, mean an absence <strong>of</strong> politics and<br />

markets (O’Donnell, 2001); much activity will take place outside the formal<br />

system. Black-market businesses are difficult to tax, to regulate, and to<br />

restrain so that legitimate enterprises may flourish; political parties and<br />

civil society may be similarly preempted by private followings. Inefficient<br />

and undemocratic as those illicit activities may be, they can be more<br />

rewarding than legitimate alternatives. Therefore, further economic and<br />

political liberalization in the absence <strong>of</strong> strong institutions may only add<br />

more fuel to the fire (Satter, 2003). The rule <strong>of</strong> law can become a fiction in<br />

an Oligarchs and Clans setting, while the expectation <strong>of</strong> corruption and<br />

violence becomes a kind <strong>of</strong> self-fulfilling prophecy (Leitzel, 2002:41).<br />

Oligarchs and Clans: three cases<br />

Russia, Mexico, and the Philippines all fit this pr<strong>of</strong>ile in somewhat<br />

differing ways. Russia saw the fall <strong>of</strong> a dictatorial (if ossified) state and a<br />

planned economy that had sustained development in some respects while<br />

impeding it in many more. Mexico’s most recent liberalization has been<br />

political: Vicente Fox’s presidential victory in 2000 was the first national<br />

defeat for the Institutional Revolutionary Party (Partido Revolucionario<br />

Institutional, or PRI) since its founding seventy-one years before. But<br />

during the 1980s the state’s role in the economy was cut back significantly<br />

(Levy and Bruhn, 2001: 165–179). Economic liberalization in the<br />

Philippines intensified during the early 1990s (Ringuet and Estrada,<br />

2003: 237–239), although its pace has slowed in recent years (Montesano,<br />

2004: 98–99); political liberalization dates from the ‘‘People Power’’<br />

revolution <strong>of</strong> 1986. All three countries – Russia most <strong>of</strong> all – <strong>of</strong>fer major<br />

economic opportunities based on natural resources, emergent domestic<br />

markets, and, particularly in Mexico, manufacturing. They are middleincome<br />

countries (the Philippines perhaps excepted) and their Human<br />

Development scores reflect a similar ranking. However, table 6.1 also<br />

indicates institutional weaknesses, less pronounced in Mexico (a transitional<br />

case in terms <strong>of</strong> corruption syndromes, as we shall see) but very<br />

serious in Russia. Ratings for institutional and social capacity are well<br />

below those seen in the Elite Cartel cases – not to mention those for

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!