07.01.2013 Aufrufe

Festschrift für Fritz W. Scharpf - MPIfG

Festschrift für Fritz W. Scharpf - MPIfG

Festschrift für Fritz W. Scharpf - MPIfG

MEHR ANZEIGEN
WENIGER ANZEIGEN

Erfolgreiche ePaper selbst erstellen

Machen Sie aus Ihren PDF Publikationen ein blätterbares Flipbook mit unserer einzigartigen Google optimierten e-Paper Software.

Héritier · Containing Negative Integration 103<br />

2 Negative Integration Prevails<br />

The more specific claim of the argument that negative integration prevails is<br />

that abolishing tariffs and quantitative restrictions on trade among member<br />

states and establishing free and undistorted competition have been at the<br />

centre of European law-making. It has been possible to pursue this lawmaking<br />

agenda relatively easily, as it entails “low political visibility through<br />

individual interventions against Treaty infringements by the Commission<br />

and the preliminary ruling of the European Court of Justice” (<strong>Scharpf</strong><br />

1999: 50). Positive integration, on the contrary, depends upon the agreement<br />

of member state governments in the Council of Ministers and, increasingly,<br />

upon the acquiescence of the EP as well. “This fundamental institutional<br />

difference is sufficient to explain the frequently deplored asymmetry between<br />

negative and positive integration in EC policy-making” (<strong>Scharpf</strong><br />

1999: 51).<br />

In addition, there is the fact that the Treaties, by stating the goal of establishing<br />

a common market, have defined very specific measures for<br />

gradually eliminating tariffs and quantitative restrictions on imports (Arts.<br />

12–17, 30–35 of the Treaty Establishing the European Community, TEC).<br />

They all can be achieved by a non-political decision-making route.<br />

By contrast, the prohibitions against national regulations operating as non-tariff<br />

barriers … were not only worded less precisely, but also qualified by the numerous<br />

and in part rather vague “public order” exceptions of Art. 36 TEC.<br />

(<strong>Scharpf</strong> 1999: 51)<br />

These prohibitions could only be overcome through “positive” harmonization<br />

decisions by the Council. Likewise, competition law was relatively precise<br />

with respect to private enterprises (Arts. 85–87 TEC), but less clear and<br />

shot through with important exceptions with regard to the prohibition against<br />

competition-distorting state subsidies (Arts. 92–94 TEC). Even more ambivalent<br />

is the wording of Art. 90 TEC [new Art. 86 TEC – A.H.] which, in paragraph 1,<br />

obliges member states to respect the rules of competition law with regard to<br />

“public undertakings and undertakings to which Member States grant special or<br />

exclusive rights”, but in its paragraph 2 exempts undertakings entrusted with the<br />

operation of services of general economic interest or having the character of a<br />

revenue-producing monopoly. If these were to be touched at all, one could have<br />

thought that any moves toward liberalization would depend upon “political action”<br />

by the Council of Ministers – just as political action had been necessary to

Hurra! Ihre Datei wurde hochgeladen und ist bereit für die Veröffentlichung.

Erfolgreich gespeichert!

Leider ist etwas schief gelaufen!