07.01.2013 Aufrufe

Festschrift für Fritz W. Scharpf - MPIfG

Festschrift für Fritz W. Scharpf - MPIfG

Festschrift für Fritz W. Scharpf - MPIfG

MEHR ANZEIGEN
WENIGER ANZEIGEN

Sie wollen auch ein ePaper? Erhöhen Sie die Reichweite Ihrer Titel.

YUMPU macht aus Druck-PDFs automatisch weboptimierte ePaper, die Google liebt.

106 II · Politik und Demokratie in Europa<br />

To what extent is this expectation confirmed in the subsequent regulatory<br />

activities in the network industries, and how can this be accounted for?<br />

3 General Argument<br />

In search of a general argument for why market-correcting or redistributive<br />

policies are difficult to achieve in Europe, we find useful insights in the<br />

policy analysis literature linking policy types to the structure of the decision-making<br />

political entity. It was Caputo and Cole (1985), in discussing<br />

revenue-sharing schemes between the federal government and the states in<br />

the US of the 1970s and 80s, who argued that redistributive goals can only<br />

be achieved in a hierarchically structured system (see also <strong>Scharpf</strong> 1991;<br />

Windhoff-Héritier 1980). The underlying rationale is that decentralized political<br />

units in a confederated political system, which have a voice in the<br />

shaping of policies at the central level, would be unable to agree on redistributive<br />

measures in which one political sub-unit gains at the cost of the<br />

others. Market-correcting redistributive policies can only be adopted in a<br />

hierarchical polity, where the highest governmental level can impose redistributive<br />

decisions and does not depend on the formal acquiescence of decentral<br />

units. Or, as <strong>Fritz</strong> <strong>Scharpf</strong> argued in 1991:<br />

As was recognized in the Coase theorem itself, the potential for redistribution is<br />

reduced as one moves from “government” to “contract” and from “hierarchical”<br />

to “unanimous” decisions. While hierarchical authorities or hegemonic powers<br />

are free to disregard any interests and to choose any distributive rule, and while<br />

majoritarian decisions may at least disregard minority, the unanimity rule eliminates<br />

the possibility of involuntary redistribution. (<strong>Scharpf</strong> 1991: 60)<br />

In further elaboration of this basic argument, conditions have been specified<br />

under which redistributive policy goals can be achieved in a confederate<br />

system, too. One of these conditions was formulated by Coase: If winners<br />

compensated losers, the latter would be willing to support a redistributive<br />

policy. That is, the gains achieved by redistribution have to be large enough<br />

that the losers – at least in theoretical terms – can be compensated. Political<br />

process can, however, also make a difference. If those who are likely to<br />

emerge as winners from a redistributive decision organize collectively and<br />

mobilize to exert pressure on central decision-making (Windhoff-Héritier<br />

1980), the dynamics of a multi-level polity might lead to the incorporation

Hurra! Ihre Datei wurde hochgeladen und ist bereit für die Veröffentlichung.

Erfolgreich gespeichert!

Leider ist etwas schief gelaufen!