07.01.2013 Aufrufe

Festschrift für Fritz W. Scharpf - MPIfG

Festschrift für Fritz W. Scharpf - MPIfG

Festschrift für Fritz W. Scharpf - MPIfG

MEHR ANZEIGEN
WENIGER ANZEIGEN

Erfolgreiche ePaper selbst erstellen

Machen Sie aus Ihren PDF Publikationen ein blätterbares Flipbook mit unserer einzigartigen Google optimierten e-Paper Software.

V. Schmidt · The Boundaries of “Bounded Generalizations” 325<br />

their membership and the scope of their accepted and expected range of activities<br />

and powers, facilitates and constrains their range of choices, and influences<br />

how they evaluate the outcomes achieved by their choices. In short,<br />

the institutional setting shapes actors’ preferences and perceptions (<strong>Scharpf</strong><br />

1997: 38–40) while defining actor constellations and actors’ range of modes<br />

of interaction.<br />

There is no room here, nor need, to go into the details of the game-theoretically<br />

elucidated strategic institutional interactions that are so well analyzed<br />

in Games Real Actors Play and so well illustrated in <strong>Scharpf</strong>’s more<br />

empirical work on democratic governance (e.g., <strong>Scharpf</strong> 1996, 1999) or political<br />

economy (e.g., <strong>Scharpf</strong> 1990, 2000a). Suffice to say here that <strong>Scharpf</strong><br />

identifies the “games real actors play” by providing modular constructs that<br />

represent incomplete theories linking actor constellations and modes of interaction<br />

in particular institutional settings, against a background of a given<br />

set of policy problems, legacies, and actor attributes. These have a rational<br />

choice flavor where they can be linked analytically; but many can only be<br />

linked through narrative connections between partial theories which provide<br />

empirical as well as analytic support (<strong>Scharpf</strong> 1997: 32). These games serve<br />

as tools for analysis which seek to predict how real actors in given institutional<br />

settings would respond to a challenge if they followed strategic logic.<br />

When they do, the explanation stops here. When they don’t, the explanation<br />

points to where one needs to search for other explanatory factors.<br />

With these tools, <strong>Scharpf</strong> has been highly successful in providing gametheoretic<br />

analyses of a wide range of policy problems that “real actors” have<br />

sought to solve. He has demonstrated that whereas the EU has high problem-solving<br />

capacity in cases of “negative integration,” where it engages in<br />

market-making by following the deregulatory logic of the Treaties, it has<br />

comparatively little in “positive integration,” because the attempt to correct<br />

market failures, whether in terms of fiscal policy or social policy, is stymied<br />

by EU decision rules that create joint-decision traps where actors’ preferences<br />

differ (<strong>Scharpf</strong> 1996, 1999). Moreover, <strong>Scharpf</strong>’s analytic framework<br />

has also enabled him to explain the vast array of changes (or lack thereof) in<br />

the welfare state. Thus, for example, he has explained the problem-solving<br />

capacity of the Netherlands beginning in the early l980s by contrast with<br />

other multi-actor Continental welfare states at the same time, such as Belgium,<br />

largely in terms of Dutch actors’ new orientations – the unions’ willingness<br />

to allow capital a higher level of profit in return for more jobs – and<br />

renewed modes of interaction – a return to cooperative corporatist negotiation<br />

between the social partners that brought greater labor flexibility and

Hurra! Ihre Datei wurde hochgeladen und ist bereit für die Veröffentlichung.

Erfolgreich gespeichert!

Leider ist etwas schief gelaufen!