13.12.2012 Views

ancient cities

ancient cities

ancient cities

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

ole as well. But the notion that size matters has<br />

also been embraced by opponents of annexation.<br />

Many residents of small communities like their<br />

connection to small city governments. Land speculators<br />

sometimes prefer working with smaller governments,<br />

and those interested in city services can<br />

also find advantages in them.<br />

These traditional pro and con arguments now<br />

take place in the context of large-scale suburban<br />

sprawl. Opponents of suburban sprawl, and of the<br />

political fragmentation that generates it, frequently<br />

favor making annexation easy. Supporters<br />

of metropolitan fragmentation—or, as they are<br />

more likely to put it, people who favor offering<br />

potential residents a wide choice of communities<br />

to live in—oppose it. Current annexation debates<br />

also take place in metropolitan areas that are characterized<br />

by wide disparities between neighboring<br />

jurisdictions in terms of income, race, and ethnicity.<br />

The greater these disparities, the more likely it<br />

is that annexation will be fiercely contested.<br />

The way in which these arguments for and<br />

against annexation are resolved is significantly<br />

affected by the different legal structures for annexation<br />

established by state law. Some states (such as<br />

Texas) have adopted rules that foster annexation<br />

and others (such as Massachusetts) have adopted<br />

rules that inhibit it. Many people assume that a territory<br />

cannot be annexed over the objection of its<br />

residents. But that is only one of the possible legal<br />

structures for annexation decisions. The state legislature<br />

can enlarge a city’s territory on its own without<br />

a vote either of the expanding city or of the<br />

territory to be annexed. The state legislature can also<br />

authorize local elections. Yet these elections can be<br />

organized in different ways. Residents of both<br />

the annexing city and the annexed territory can be<br />

entitled to vote on the annexation proposal, but<br />

their votes can be counted either together, in one<br />

ballot box, or separately, with a majority required in<br />

each of the two jurisdictions. The dual ballot box<br />

option empowers the territory sought to be annexed<br />

to veto the annexation, whereas the single ballot box<br />

option (assuming that the annexing city has a larger<br />

population) makes annexation easier to accomplish.<br />

Some states organize annexation by empowering<br />

only the residents of the annexing city or its city<br />

council to approve annexation. Under this scheme,<br />

no vote at all takes place in the annexed territory.<br />

Other states do the opposite: They enable the<br />

Annexation<br />

29<br />

residents of the annexed territory to vote but deny the<br />

vote to residents of the annexing city. Like the choice<br />

between a single and dual ballot box, these alternative<br />

structures can foster or inhibit annexation.<br />

States clearly have the freedom to organize<br />

annexation in any of these ways. All of the voting<br />

procedures—along with the power of the state<br />

legislature to make the decision itself—have been<br />

upheld as constitutional. The leading U.S. Supreme<br />

Court case, decided in 1907, is Hunter v. Pittsburgh.<br />

That case upheld the single ballot box procedure.<br />

It allowed Pittsburgh to annex neighboring<br />

Allegheny over the objection made by Allegheny’s<br />

residents that permitting the annexation, after a<br />

majority of Allegheny’s residents voted against it,<br />

would deprive them of protected property rights.<br />

The justification for such a combined ballot box<br />

is majority rule. A decision has to be made about<br />

how best to govern an expanding metropolitan<br />

region. If a majority of the combined territory favors<br />

an annexation, a minority, often a small minority,<br />

should not be able to stand in its way. The justification<br />

for the dual ballot box, however, can also be<br />

framed as a vindication of majority rule. In this case,<br />

the majorities of the two areas are considerably<br />

separately, not together. It is thought to be unfair,<br />

from this point of view, for a territory to be absorbed<br />

into another government structure over the objections<br />

of a majority of its residents.<br />

The state government’s selection from the list of<br />

possible legal structures can have a considerable<br />

effect on whether annexation takes place. It is easier<br />

to annex a territory if it cannot veto the proposal.<br />

Nevertheless, one should not assume that the choice<br />

of procedure always dictates the result. The initial<br />

annexation that enlarged Boston in the nineteenth<br />

century was a result simply of state legislation.<br />

Later, the law changed to require the consent of the<br />

annexed territory. Yet that consent was forthcoming<br />

from many suburbs, ending only with Brookline’s<br />

rejection of annexation in 1874. Similarly, the<br />

annexations in Los Angeles from 1909 to 1915<br />

took place after a majority in both the annexing<br />

and annexed territories supported the city’s growth.<br />

Moreover, allowing the annexing city to decide the<br />

issue by itself also does not determine the result.<br />

The population of the annexing city can decide that<br />

the annexation is not in that city’s best interest.<br />

Determining whether a jurisdiction “consents”<br />

to an annexation is sometimes complex. Although

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!